Occasional Paper Series
Stablecoins:
Implications for monetary policy,
financial stability, market
infrastructure and payments, and
banking supervision in the euro area
ECB Crypto-Assets Task Force
No 247 / September 2020
Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB).
The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
1
Contents
Abstract 2
Executive summary 3
1 Introduction 5
2 Characterisation of stablecoins 7
3 Recent developments and current status of stablecoins 11
4 Risk asse ssment 17
4.1 Monetary policy 19
4.2 Financial stability 22
4.3 Market infrastructures and payments 23
4.4 Banking supervision and prudential regulation 27
5 Conclusions 31
References 33
Acknowledgements 35
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
2
Abstract
This paper summarises the outcome of an analysis of stablecoins undertaken by the
ECB Crypto-Assets Task Force. At the time of writing, the stablecoin debate lacks a
common taxonomy and unambiguous terminology. This paper applies a definition that
distinguishes stablecoins from existing forms of currencies regardless of the
technology used and characterises stablecoin arrangements based on the functions
they fulfil. This approach emphasises the role of technology-neutral regulation in
preventing arbitrage, as well as comprehensive Eurosystem oversight, irrespective of
stablecoins regulatory status. Against this background, this paper assesses
stablecoins implications for the euro area based on three scenarios for the uptake of
stablecoins: (i) as a crypto-assets accessory function; (ii) as a new payment method;
and (iii) as an alternative store of value. While the first scenario is merely the
continuation of the current state of the market and, thus far, has not posed concerns
for the financial sector and/or central bank tasks, stablecoins of the type envisaged in
the second scenario may reach a scale such that financial stability risks can become
material, and the safety and efficiency of the payment system may be affected. The
third scenario is both the least plausible and the most relevant from a monetary policy
perspective. The paper concludes that the Eurosystem relies on appropriate
regulation, oversight, and supervision to manage the implications of stablecoins (and
the risks that stem from them) on its mandate and tasks under plausible scenarios.
The Eurosystem continues monitoring the evolution of the stablecoin market and
stands ready to respond to rapid changes in all possible scenarios.
Keywords: stablecoins, implications of stablecoins, regulation, oversight
JEL codes: E42, G21, G23, O33
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
3
Executive summary
Stablecoins are a relatively recent payment innovation, which has already
been the subject of much debate particularly in the last year. Initially,
terminology can be a confusing, even misleading, element in the discussion
surrounding new technological phenomena. This report builds on an earlier definition
of stablecoins as digital units of value that differ from existing forms of currencies (e.g.
deposits, e-money, etc.) and rely on a set of stabilisation tools to minimise fluctuations
in their price against a currency, or basket thereof.
1
Different types of stablecoins have
emerged.
2
To maintain a stable price, some stablecoin initiatives pledge to hold funds
and/or other assets (“collateral”) against which stablecoin holdings may be redeemed
or exchanged. Stablecoin arrangements fulfil multiple functions: from the stabilisation
of the value of stablecoins to the transfer of value, and interaction with users.
Recent initiatives may stimulate the adoption of stablecoins and raise
implications for public policy, regulation, oversight and supervision. The extent
of these implications will depend on the specific scenario for the uptake of stablecoins.
This article identifies three such scenarios. Stablecoins could have a “crypto-assets
accessory function” that allow securing crypto-asset revenues in less volatile assets
without leaving the crypto-ecosystem (first scenario), or become a new payment
method” (second scenario), or even an “alternative store of value” (third scenario).
These scenarios depend on the specific features of stablecoins the second and third
scenarios are reliant on stablecoin types that offer high levels of price stability and
credible redemption policies and on key drivers for their adoption (e.g. convenience
and ease of use as compared to existing instruments).
This analysis shows that a stablecoin arrangement of the type entailed in the
second scenario (“new payment method”) could reach a scale of operations
such that fragilities within the stablecoin arrangement itself, and its links to the
financial system, may give rise to financial stability risks. Stablecoins are
vulnerable to liquidity “runs. Where a stablecoin is exchanged/redeemed at the
market value of its collateral, a run could occur if end users are confronted with the
prospect that the stablecoin’s collateral may lose its value. Runs could also occur in
the case of an arrangement that guarantees redeemability at face value if the
stablecoin sponsor is perceived as lacking sufficient loss-absorbing capacity. In these
events, the liquidation of assets to cover redemptions could have negative contagion
effects on the financial system.
As part of their transfer of value function, stablecoins can also have
implications for the safety and efficiency of payment systems and, under
certain conditions, even pose systemic risk. The specific sources of risks and
inefficiencies would depend on the design of the transfer of value system, ranging from
the legal basis to governance (especially in a highly decentralised arrangement), the
1
See Bullmann et al. (2019).
2
See European Central Bank (2019).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
4
arrangements choice of settlement asset, operational complexities and, among other
things, cyber risks.
Euro deposits and cash are expected to be resilient to the possible advent of an
alternative store of value. In the event that this less plausible alternative store of
valuescenario materialises, significant implications for monetary policy could arise.
This scenario involves stablecoin types that hold safe assets as collateral to achieve
high levels of stability of the stablecoin’s value. Their significant uptake could increase
demand for safe assets by stablecoin arrangements and might have a negative impact
on price formation, collateral valuation, money market functioning and the monetary
policy space. Banks’ intermediation capacity might also be challenged. That being
said, the current negative interest rate environment could place significant constraints
on the profitability of a non-interest-bearing stablecoin, as its collateral would be
remunerated negatively.
The Eurosystem can use a range of tools to manage the implications of
stablecoins in plausible scenarios. The Eurosystem’s oversight framework will
cover stablecoin arrangements that qualify as payment systems regardless of the
technology used and their organisational setup. Furthermore, the Eurosystem is
reviewing its oversight framework for payment instruments and schemes, with a view
to broadening its scope to include any electronic payment instruments that enable end
users to send and receive value, including based on stablecoins. The Single
Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) can rely on the existing approach for supervision and
require banks to put in place an appropriate risk management framework for
addressing risks resulting from their potential involvement in stablecoin
arrangements/ecosystems.
These efforts need to be complemented by adequate, internationally
coordinated regulation and cooperative oversight and supervision. The
European Union (EU) and Eurosystem regulatory and oversight response should
follow the principle of “same business, same risks, same rules” to ensure a level
playing field by applying existing requirements as appropriate and closing gaps (e.g.
through suitable prudential requirements for large stablecoin issuers) in a manner
consistent with the guidance of international standard setting bodies. Appropriate
accounting and prudential treatments should be identified in a timely fashion.
Overseers and supervisors should strengthen cooperation arrangements in the light of
ecosystems spanning multiple jurisdictions.
The Eurosystem continues to monitor the evolution of the stablecoins market
and stands ready to respond to rapid changes in all possible scenarios. Current
initiatives could alter the European payments landscape and may exacerbate
Europe’s dependence on global players in the field of payments. This may call for, inter
alia, fostering central bank innovations to cater for a changed environment in the
payments space and altered conditions for the exercise of a central banks core
mandate.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
5
1 Introduction
The ECB Internal Crypto-Assets Task Force (ICA-TF) was established in 2018
with a mandate to deepen the analysis around virtual currencies and
crypto-assets. The ICA-TF analysis focuses on assessing and identifying how to
contain any adverse impacts of crypto-assets on the use of the euro, the Eurosystems
monetary policy, the safety and efficiency of financial market infrastructures and
payments, and the stability of the financial system. This analysis serves as a basis for
European Central Bank (ECB) contributions to policy discussions in the European
System of Central Banks (ESCB), the EU and other international fora, and with the
relevant regulatory authorities. The Occasional Paper
3
published in May 2019
summarises the ICA-TF analysis on crypto-assets. Since then, the ICA-TF has been
monitoring market developments with a view to keeping this assessment up to date.
While stablecoins are not a new development the currently most traded
stablecoin dates back to 2014 recent initiatives have brought about a
paradigm shift in the public debate on stablecoins. In particular, the
announcement of one such initiative Libra in June 2019 triggered a
globally-coordinated response under the umbrella of the G7. The G7 working group
report on the impact of global stablecoins was published in October 2019.
4
From then
on, the G20, the Financial Stability Board (FSB), and several standard setting bodies
have also embarked on efforts to address the potential risks while harnessing the
potential of technological innovation.
5
The ECB participates in these efforts via the
relevant fora. In December 2019 the Council and the European Commission released
a joint statement on stablecoins, calling for a coordinated approach to tackling the
challenges raised by global stablecoins, and swift action on the part of the relevant
authorities in cooperation with the ECB.
6
Building on ongoing work at the international level and leveraging its
crypto-asset analytical framework, the ICA-TF has analysed stablecoins with a
view to identifying their potential implications for the Eurosystem’s monetary
policy, as well as euro area financial stability, market infrastructure and
payments, and banking supervision. This analysis is not intended as an evaluation
of the merits of stablecoins versus their drawbacks, but rather serves as a contribution
to the development of a safe environment for innovations in payments and financial
services.
This paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides a characterisation of
stablecoins and stablecoin arrangements. Section 3 summarises recent
developments and current status of stablecoin markets. Then, Section 4 provides an
assessment of stablecoins implications, covering monetary policy, financial stability,
3
See ECB Crypto-Asse ts Task Force (2019).
4
G7 Working Group on Stablecoins (2019).
5
See Financial Stability Board (2020).
6
See Council of the European Union (2019).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
6
market infrastructure and payment dimensions, as well as the banking supervision
and prudential regulation perspective. Section 5 concludes.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
7
2 Characterisation of stablecoins
Stablecoins can be generally defined as digital units of value that are not a form
of any specific currency, or basket thereof, and that rely on a set of stabilisation
tools to minimise fluctuations of their price against such currency, or
currencies.
7
To maintain a stable price against the currency, or currencies, of
reference, some stablecoins pledge to hold funds and/or other assets (“collateral”)
against which stablecoin holdings can be redeemed. Alternatively, stablecoins rely on
a mechanism that attempts to match demand and supply so as to maintain parity
between the stablecoin and the reference currency, or currencies, and to guide users’
expectations on its future value (algorithmic stablecoins). An element common to all
stablecoin initiatives is their reliance on an open market to reinstitute par value by
providing arbitrage opportunities. Stablecoin arrangements fulfil multiple functions
including the stabilisation of the value of stablecoins, the transfer of stablecoins and
the facilitation of the interaction with the users via a dedicated interface.
8
Existing forms of currencies and other traditional assets that use innovative
technologies are not the focus of this analysis. Examples include e-money and
commercial bank deposits recorded by means of distributed ledger technology (DLT),
which nevertheless may be marketed as stablecoins. Wholesale digital tokens for the
settlement of large-value transactions between institutions (usually banks), which
represent an existing claim, either on a specific issuer or on underlying assets or
funds, or some other right or interest
9
and often referred to as stablecoins are not
addressed in this paper. Central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) are also excluded
from the scope of this analysis insofar as they are a liability of the central bank.
Based on their design, stablecoins have been classified into four types: (i)
tokenised funds
10
; (ii) off-chain collateralised stablecoins; (iii) on-chain
collateralised stablecoins; and (iv) algorithmic stablecoins.
11
Table 1
summarises the main characteristics of each stablecoin type. Stablecoins can also be
distinguished on the basis of their geographic scope, whereby “global” stablecoins
would encompass multiple jurisdictions in terms of their users, the entities comprising
the arrangement, and the composition of the collateral (if relevant).
7
See Bullmann et al. (2019).
8
See G7 Working Group on Stablecoins (2019).
9
See CPMI, Wholesale digital tokens, December 2019.
10
The termtokenised funds is borrowed from Bullmann et al. (2019) and is used here without prejudice to
the competent authorities determination of applicable law, i.e. whether or not the initiative can be
qualified as funds in the meaning of the Revised Payment Services Directive (PSD2). In practice, as
noted later in this paper, these initiatives share several features of supervised or overseen payment
instruments, payment schemes and payment systems.
11
Bullmann et al. (2019).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
8
Table 1
Summary table of stablecoin characteristics
issued on the receipt of: collateralised” by: redeemable at:
Tokenised
funds
funds (i.e. cash, deposits or
electronic money)
funds and/or close substitutes (i.e.
secure, low-risk, liquid assets
12
)
market value of the collateral at the
time of redemption or face value of
the stablecoin
Off-chain
collateralised
stablecoin
assets held through an accountable
entity (e.g. securities, commodities,
or crypto-assets in custody with an
intermediary)
assets held through an accountable
entity (e.g. securities, commodities,
or crypto-assets in custody with an
intermediary)
market value of the collateral at the
time of redemption
On-chain
collateralised
stablecoin
cr ypto-assets held directly on the
distributed ledger
cr ypto-assets held directly on the
distributed ledger
market value of the collateral at the
time of redemption
Algorithmic
stablecoins
cr ypto-assets or given away for free no collateral value of stablecoin is
based purely on the expectation of
its future market value
not redeemable
Source: Based on Bullmann et al. (2019).
Notes: Some stablecoin initiatives add to the pool of collateral own funds, which are raised through either fees or margin calls.
Redemptions are subject to the conditions set out in the stablecoin’s terms of service. For the purposes of this table, only voluntary
redemption is considered. Compulsory redemption occurs when the value of the collateral for a stablecoin unit drops below the level
specified within the rules of the stablecoin initiative.
Most stablecoins currently in operation (see also Section 3) do not share the
most prominent characteristic of crypto-assets, which is the absence of a
financial claim on, liability of, or proprietary right against any identifiable
entity.
13
In fact, tokenised funds and off-chain collateralised stablecoins necessitate
an accountable issuer that is responsible for safekeeping of the collateral, either
directly or through a custody agreement with a third-party, and can therefore be held to
account for satisfying holders rights.
Stablecoins that entail a claim/liability on an identifiable entity (which are not
crypto-assets as per the ECB definition) should be subject to existing
regulatory standards, as amended, to impose additional requirements where
needed.
14
Some initiatives in tokenised funds share the function and characteristics of
e-money but the application of the Electronic Money Directive (EMD2)
15
may be
insufficient on its own to address increased complexities and risks of stablecoin
business models. The application of EU investment fund regulation is also premised
on the condition that the investment fund share represents a claim of its holder on the
investment fund’s assets
16
. Otherwise the issuer would not be bound by the standard
EU regulatory framework of Undertakings for the Collective Investment in Transferable
12
See, for example, Table 1 of Point 14 of Annex I to Directive 2006/49/EC of the European Parliament and
of the Council of 14 June 2006 on the capital adequacy of investment firms and credit institutions (OJ
L 177, 30.6.2006, p. 201).
13
See ECB Crypto-assets Task Force (2019).
14
See European System of Central Banks (2020).
15
Directive 2009/110/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 16 September 2009 on the
taking up, pursuit and prudential supervision of the business of electronic money institutions amending
Directives 2005/60/EC and 2006/48/EC and repealing Directive 2000/46/EC (OJ L 267, 10.10.2009,
p. 7). See Article 2.2 electronic money means electronically, including magnetically, stored monetary
value as represented by a claim on the issuer which is issued on receipt of funds for the purpose of
making payment transactions as defined in Point 5 of Article 4 of Directive 2007/64/EC, and which is
accepted by a natural or legal person other than the electronic money issuer. See also EBA (2019a),
which outlines the circumstance in which assets will qualify as electronic money and will therefore fall
within the scope of the EMD2.
16
See Adachi et al. (2020).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
9
Securities
17
or Alternative Investment Fund Managers (AIFM)
18
, or by the regulation
of Money Market Funds.
19
Irrespective of the regulatory treatment of stablecoins, the function of
stablecoin arrangements that caters for the execution of transfer orders may
qualify as payment system for the purposes of Eurosystem oversight. The
ECB Regulation on oversight requirements for systemically important payment
systems
20
(SIPS Regulation) defines a payment system as “a formal arrangement
between three or more participants, [] with common rules and standardised
arrangements for the execution of transfer orders between the participants”. Within
this definition, transfer order and participants are defined in broad terms that allow
accommodation of “any instruction which results in the assumption or discharge of a
payment obligation” (Article 2(i) of the Settlement Finality Directive
21
) and any “entity
that is identified or recognised by a payment system and, either directly or indirectly, is
allowed to send transfer orders to that system and is capable of receiving transfer
orders from it” (Article 2 (18) of SIPS Regulation), respectively. To the extent that
stablecoin arrangements qualify as payment systems, the Eurosystem payment
system oversight framework based on the Principles for Financial Market
Infrastructures (PFMI) of the Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures
(CPMI) and the International Organisation of Securities Commissions (IOSCO)
22
would apply.
Similarly, the function of stablecoin arrangements that sets standardised and
common rules for the execution of payment transactions between end users
could qualify as apayment scheme. Where stablecoins are denominated in,
funded by or collateralised by euro, the governance body that is responsible for the
overall functioning of the payment scheme might be subject to the revised and
consolidated Eurosystem oversight framework for payment instruments and schemes.
This framework, which is currently under development, would be applicable to any
electronic payment instruments that enable end users to send and receive value, and
hence would apply irrespective of the qualification of the asset as funds under the
Revised Payment Services Directive (PSD2).
23
Furthermore, individual entities comprising a stablecoin arrangements
ecosystem could take up activities to offer services or products that may well
be subject to licensing regimes under EU or national law. Depending on the
17
Directive 2009/65/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 on the coordination
of laws, regulations and administrative provisions relating to undertakings for collective investment in
transferable securities (UCITS) (OJ L 302, 17.11.2009, p. 32).
18
See Directive 2011/61/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 8 June 2011 on Alternative
Investment Fund Managers and amending Directives 2003/41/EC and 2009/65/EC and Regulations (EC)
No 1060/2009 and (EU) No 1095/2010 (OJ L 174, 1.7.2011, p. 1).
19
See Regulation (EU) 2017/1131 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 14 June 2017 on
money market funds (OJ L 169, 30.6.2017, p. 8).
20
Regulation of the European Central Bank (EU) No 795/2014 of 3 July 2014 on oversight requirements for
systemically important payment systems (ECB/2014/28) (OJ L 217, 23.07.2014, p.16).
21
Directive 98/26/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 May 1998 on settlement finality
in payment and securities settlement systems, (OJ L 166, 11.6.1998, p. 45).
22
See Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures and the International Organisation of Securities
Commissions (2012).
23
See footnote 9.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
10
products they offer, and the services they provide, several legal and regulatory
regimes could apply to them (including MiFID2
24
, PSD2, AIFMD, etc.). The entire set
of applicable frameworks could only be identified on a case-by-case basis.
Stablecoin arrangements should be subject to relevant regulation, oversight,
and supervision across all relevant functions. Efforts are underway in the EU to
examine the applicability of existing rules and evaluate the need for new legislation as
appropriate. These efforts should prioritise substance over form and apply the same
rules to all activities that give rise to the same risks, irrespective of the technologies
used or the type of service provider/operator. Furthermore, regulation, oversight and
supervision should cover all relevant functions comprising a stablecoin ecosystem,
including those that are not governed by a stablecoin’s issuer or scheme manager.
Finally, given the cross-border nature of stablecoin arrangements, international
coordination is crucial to ensure consistency and prevent regulatory arbitrage.
24
Directive 2014/65/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 May 2014 on markets in
financial instruments and amending Directive 2002/92/EC and Directive 2011/61/EU (OJ L 173,
12.6.2014, p. 349).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
11
3 Recent developments and current status
of stablecoins
A growing number of stablecoin initiatives have been reported in the last few
years especially since 2018: of these, 50 are currently traded on crypto-asset
trading platforms.
25 26
Most traded stablecoins were launched in 2018 (around 40%)
while those that started to trade this year account for 16% of all traded stablecoins.
Tokenised funds are estimated to be the most numerous stablecoin type, followed by
on-chain collateral and algorithmic
27
. Europe, including the United Kingdom and
Switzerland, hosts a third of traded stablecoins, whereas a quarter have their
headquarters in the euro area. Stablecoin market dynamism is also evidenced by a
relatively high number of reportedly closed initiatives.
28
Stablecoins trade at levels comparable to those of bitcoin the most prominent
crypto-asset with Tether, a stablecoin, in a dominant position (see Chart 1).
Trading volumes of stablecoins
29
showed dynamic increases since spring 2019,
driven by the release of the initial Libra White Paper. However, by mid-2020 they
returned broadly to pre-Libra levels. Trading volumes peaked again in 2020, following
the outbreak of the coronavirus (COVID-19) crisis and related financial market and
crypto-asset turbulences including a bitcoin price nosedive which led investors to turn
to stablecoins.
25
Blockdata (2019) reports about 134 project announcements as of 2019.
26
Number currently being traded on crypto-asset trading platforms based on information retrieved from
Coinmarketcap.
27
See also Bullmann et al. (2019).
28
Blockdata (2019) reports 26 initiatives closed (i.e. no longer operational) as of 2019.
29
Trading volumes provide a partial measure of the use of the stablecoins generally intended as a means of
exchange in the real economy. Data on the use of stablecoins for retail payments are not currently
available.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
12
Chart 1
Trading volumes
(USD billion, Jan. 2018 June 2020, end-of-month data)
Sources: Cr yptocompare and ECB calculations.
Notes: The coverage included on the chart is as follows: major crypto-assets: BCH (bitcoin cash), BTC (bitcoin), EOS (Eos), ETH
(Ethereum), XLM (Stellar), XRP (Ripple) and major stablecoins: DAI (Dai coin), GUSD (Gemini Dollar), PAX (Paxos Standard), TUSD
(TrueUSD), USDC (USD coin) and USDT (Tether).
Trading data confirms earlier findings that the prevalent use case of stablecoins
is to provide a store of value for revenues related to crypto-asset investments.
Trades of Tether versus those of crypto-assets, and especially versus those of bitcoin,
constitute the vast majority of all trades, while trades of Tether versus those of other
stablecoins and fiat currencies are very small (see Chart 2). Although most
stablecoins are referenced to international fiat currencies of USD, EUR, GBP, or
baskets thereof, the volumes of direct trades of stablecoins versus those of fiat
currencies are insignificant, which further supports the aforementioned observation
regarding the original stablecoin function.
Chart 2
Trading volumes of Tether vis-vis crypto-assets and fiat currencies
(percentages, Jan. 2018 June 2020, end-of-month data)
Sources: Cryptocompare and ECB calculations.
Note: For coverage see Chart 1.
-
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
01/18 04/18 07/18 10/18 01/19 04/19 07/19 10/19 01/20 04/20
Major crypto-assets
BTC (bitcoin)
Major stablecoins
USDT (Tether)
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
01/18 04/18 07/18 10/18 01/19 04/19 07/19 10/19 01/20 04/20
BTC (bitcoin)
Other major crypto-assets
Major stablecoins
Selected fiat currencies
Other
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
13
Market capitalisation of major stablecoins represents a fraction (6.5%) of that of
bitcoin, however it increased multi-fold only in 2020. The driver behind the
increased market capitalisation was a growing supply of stablecoins, which has almost
tripled for Gemini USD and more than doubled for Tether, USD Coin and DAI since the
beginning of 2020 (see Chart 3). The increased supply might have resulted from
higher demand from investors amid the start of the COVID-19 crisis.
30
Chart 3
Market capitalisation
(USD billion and percentage, Jan. 2018 12 July 2020, daily data)
Sources: Coinmarketcap and ECB calculations.
Note: See Chart 1 for names of the stablecoins.
With respect to prices, the volatility of stablecoin prices is less pronounced
than that of popular crypto-assets (see Chart 4). The price volatility varies across
stablecoin types, with tokenised funds showing the lowest volatility. Price volatility of
both stablecoins and crypto-assets peaked in the first quarter of 2020, while the price
volatility of the latter decreased afterwards to the lowest levels since 2019. Price
volatility for stablecoins also decreased, although to a lesser degree. Increased
volatility for some stablecoins may suggest difficulties in competing against other
dominant stablecoins and also vulnerabilities of stablecoin design.
30
See, for example, Coin Metrics (2020).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
14
Chart 4
Price volatility
Selected non-stablecoin crypto-assets
(1 Jan. 2019 30 June 2020)
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
BTC
Minimum
1st quartile
Median
3rd quartile
Maximum
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
ETH
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
XRP
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
BCH
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
EOS
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
XLM
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
15
Stablecoins
(1 Jan. 2019 30 June 2020)
Sources: Coinmarketcap and ECB calculations.
Notes: Volatility is measured as the standard deviation of day-to-day per cent changes of rolling seven day windows. Volatility is
annualised. Coverage of crypto-asset as in Chart 1.
Insights into the current linkages of stablecoins with the real economy and the
financial system are hindered by a lack of data. In general, crypto-assets and
related technology draw significant public and media attention. Looking at “alternative”
data sources, the Google Trends indicators point to significant traffic generated by the
searches of terms related to crypto-assets with growing interest in stablecoins (see
Chart 5). Turning to the reach of stablecoin initiatives via Twitter, a few hundred
thousand follow the accounts of stablecoins, with more than 100,000 followers of
Gemini Dollar. Tether and the MakerDAO have 40,000 and 47,700 followers,
respectively.
31
31
Data collected on 27 July 2020.
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
USDT
Minimum
1st quartile
Median
3rd quartile
Maximum
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
PAX
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
GUSD
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
TUSD
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
USDC
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2
2019 2020
DAI
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
16
Chart 5
Interest in crypto-assets and related searches
(interest over time, collected on 13 July 2020, weekly data)
Source: Google Trends.
Notes: Interest over time represents search interest worldwide relative to the highest point on the chart for the given region and time. A
value of 100 is the peak popularity for the term. A value of 50 means that the term is half as popular. A score of 0 means there was not
enough data for this term.
The current status of the market might change significantly as a result of new
stablecoin initiatives that purport to provide efficient means of payment for
mainstream use cases (e.g. international remittances, cash transfer
programmes, international consumer-to-business payments). Furthermore, the
involvement of large technology and consumer companies with vast user bases (as in
the case of Libra) provides a natural platform for a more significant uptake of
stablecoins.
32
32
The Libra Association is progressing swiftly on technical design and development and has recently
unveiled a revised whitepaper see Libra Association (2020). The Libra Association proposes to offer
single-currency stablecoins, in addition to a multi-currency Libra, and to tighten access to the Libra
network, among other things. It also submitted a formal application for a payment system licence under
the Swiss Financial Market Infrastructure Act to the Financial Markets Supervisory Authority.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
01/2017 05/2017 09/2017 01/2018 05/2018 09/2018 01/2019 05/2019 09/2019 01/2020 05/2020
Bitcoin
Tether
Blockchain
Stablecoin
Cryptocurrency
Facebook libra
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
17
4 Risk assessment
This section aims to illustrate the potential impact of stablecoins on the
Eurosystems ability to set the monetary policy stance, maintain financial
stability, ensure the safety and efficiency of market infrastructures and
payments, and for the conduct of banking supervision.
Based on stablecoins currently in operation (see Section 3), a risk assessme nt
would, in principle, not significantly differ from the current ECB stance on
crypto-assets
33
, but may change substantially in the light of emerging
stablecoin initiatives. The current market capitalisation does not give rise to
concerns with regard to the financial stability of the euro area. There is a shortage of
data on interlinkages between stablecoins and the financial system but overall EU
financial institutions have been applying the same conservative approach as is applied
to exposures to crypto-assets. There is limited evidence of existing stablecoins being
used for payments outside of the crypto-assets market. Therefore, at the moment, the
implications of stablecoins for economic developments and monetary policy would be
as negligible as those of crypto-assets. However, emerging initiatives have the
potential to provide attractive means of payment and possibly store of value
alternatives that can scale up rapidly and become ingrained in the payment habits of
EU consumers and businesses.
Stablecoin features play a critical role in influencing the uptake of stablecoins
as means of payment and/or store of value, which in turn determine the
concrete implications for monetary policy, financial stability, and market
infrastructures and payments. As mentioned in Section 2, stablecoins may differ
based on their design including, inter alia, levels of price stability vis-à-vis fiat
currencies and the conditions for their redemption. In addition to these features, there
are several factors that may drive user adoption of stablecoins as means of payment
and/or store of value. Three scenarios
34
for the potential use of stablecoins can be
discerned, the second and third of which are reliant on stablecoin types that offer high
levels of price stability and credible redemption policies:
crypto-assets accessory function”: stablecoins that lack the (perceived)
safety and ease of use to compete with established payment means for
mainstream use cases continue to cater mostly for the crypto-asset market
or specific user needs;
new payment method”: stablecoins that are convenient, easy to use and
also cater for payment use cases and user segments that are typically
underserved by existing solutions (e.g. cross-border payments) and at the
same time appear to mitigate the main perceived risks (e.g. loss of funds,
fraud), becoming an ordinary means of payment;
33
See ECB Crypto-Assets Task Force (2019).
34
These scenarios are simplified representations of possible future developments.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
18
alternative store of value”: stablecoins that satisfy user demand for a
cheap store of value through (more) attractive remuneration rates and are
sponsored by reputable institutions, and may therefore lead their users to
replace (part of) their euro deposits and cash with stablecoins.
A fourth scenario could be considered in which the central bank issues a CBDC
with technical and functional features similar to those of stablecoins, making
their value proposition redundant (at least for domestic payments) and
delivering the highest level of stability for users in a monetary jurisdiction. The
current paper does not elaborate on this scenario. The possibility of issuing a digital
euro, including in relation to the risks associated with stablecoins, and its specific
features, is currently being analysed by a Eurosystem high-level task force. In parallel,
several central banks (e.g. Sveriges Riksbank, Bank of Canada, People’s Bank of
China) are conducting practical experimentation mainly through Proofs of Concept
to explore the technical feasibility and the domestic and international implications of
issuing CBDC.
The first scenario is essentially the continuation of the current state of the
market, whereas the second and third scenarios are premised on future
developments changing the stablecoins landscape. Under the second scenario,
notwithstanding the progress made so far in enhancing euro payments, stablecoin
initiatives could exploit certain weaknesses or gaps (e.g. lagging instant payments
deployment and uptake, slow and costly cross-currency payments) and built-in
advantages to compete with existing electronic means of payment. A large-scale
substitution under the third scenario is less likely to materialise in situations where
confidence in the regulated financial system and financial regulators is high.
Furthermore, under certain constraints such as negative interest rates, this scenario
would be even more remote if the stablecoin initiative invested (mostly or solely) in
negatively remunerated safe assets and were to pass on the negative remuneration of
reserve assets to users (see Section 4.1.1). That said, variants of this scenario cannot
be ruled out in other economies, in which case there could be spill-overs to the euro
area.
35
The following sections of this report aim at illustrating the impact of stablecoins, in the
second and third scenarios, on the Eurosystems ability to set the monetary policy
stance for the euro area (Section 4.1), maintain financial stability (Section 4.2), and
ensure the safety and efficiency of financial market infrastructures and payments
(Section 4.3). Finally, Section 4.4 addresses aspects related to banking supervision
and prudential regulation.
35
Using the Libra project as an example, Adachi et al. (2020) provides estimates of the potential size of a
stablecoin arrangement. The Libra Reserve’s total assets under management could range from
153 billion, when Libra coin is mostly used as a means of payment, to around €3 trillion, if it becomes a
widely adopted store of value under extreme assumptions.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
19
4.1 Monetary policy
A hypothetical situation in which stablecoins become an “alternative store of
value (the third scenario described above) would have consequences for the
transmission of monetary policy and other related issues.
4.1.1 Policy constraints
A non-interest-bearing stablecoin could in principle set a zero effective lower
bound on policy rates. Widespread investment into non-interest-bearing stablecoins
could induce substitution out of assets yielding negative interest to the point where
further cuts in key policy rates no longer transmit to other interest rates in the
economy. Such shifts are, however, unlikely to occur in a negative interest rate
environment. To be able to offer a zero interest rate on a sustained basis, stablecoin
initiatives would have to charge fees to avoid significant losses or alternatively they
would have to cross-subsidise the issuance of stablecoins because collateralisation
makes them subject to the low rate environment as well. It must also be noted that
holding stablecoins entails costs such as foregoing public deposit guarantee schemes
or foreign exchange risk for multi-currency stablecoins. Foreign
currency-denominated bank deposits already offer a substitution possibility for
euro-denominated deposit holders, though they have not been materially exploited as
of now.
36
4.1.2 Impact on monetary policy transmission via banks
A hypothetical significant use of stablecoins as a store of value under the third
scenario could affect the stability and cost of bank deposit funding, which
could pose challenges for bank intermediation capacity. As the financial system
in the euro area is predominantly bank based, changes in the composition and
strength of bank balance sheets can affect the transmission of monetary policy. A
significant use of stablecoins as a “new payment method” under the second scenario
could reduce banks fee and commission income and somewhat dent their profitability,
although it would probably not significantly affect their funding conditions. Under the
third scenario, banks may need to shift from deposits to more expensive sources of
funding, thereby potentially increasing the cost of credit for households and smaller,
bank-dependent firms. Further possible implications of stablecoins for SSM banks are
discussed in Section 4.4.
36
A significant substitution towards foreign currency-denominated deposits by the money-holding sector
has not been observed yet, which is consistent with the fact that most customer deposits in the euro area
do not offer a negative interest rate. However, there are indications that, when engaging in international
transactions, some banks prefer to be paid in foreign currency rather than in reserves with the
Eurosystem, in order to avoid the negative deposit facility rate.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
20
4.1.3 Liquidity and money markets
Under the third scenario, stablecoins might affect the demand for central bank
liquidity and thereby the ECBs steering of euro money market rates. Demand for
central bank liquidity arises, inter alia, from the need to clear payments in central bank
money and to cover liquidity shocks resulting from changes in banknote demand. The
effect of stablecoins on central bank reserve demand would depend on the concrete
design of the stablecoin and the type of collateral used. The substitution of banknotes
and central bank money with stablecoins at a degree envisaged in the second
scenario could reduce the demand for ECB liquidity but would not necessarily
constrain the ability to steer short-term money market rates, as stablecoin reserves
would likely be invested in euro-denominated assets, which would respond to changes
in key policy rates.
The issuance of stablecoins might raise questions about the central bank
acting as a lender of last resort for the institutions that host the stablecoin’s
collateral, as users will expect full convertibility into fiat currency. Even if
stablecoins are collateralised with high-quality assets (such as commercial bank
deposits, money market fund shares and government bonds)
37
as in, for example,
tokenised funds a sudden run on stablecoins would require the liquidation of
collateral assets, potentially creating funding strains not only for the stablecoin issuer
and for banks but also for investment funds and other entities that do not have direct
access to central bank lending operations.
4.1.4 Safe asset demand
Under the third scenario, stablecoins collateralised by high-quality liquid
assets (e.g. tokenised funds) might increase the demand for safe assets,
thereby possibly affecting asset price formation, collateral valuation, money
market functioning and monetary policy space. In the event that deposit holders
move from bank deposits to stablecoins, the demand for safe assets could increase
overall if the stablecoin arrangement holds a large share of such assets as part of the
collateral. Safe asset demand may be especially affected if in other jurisdictions
non-euro deposits are substituted for euro-denominated stablecoins on a large scale,
as these inflows would have to be collateralised by high-quality assets denominated in
euro. A higher demand for euro-denominated safe assets might affect the risk-free
yield curve, the exchange rate, asset prices generally and collateral valuation, with
potential implications for rate volatility in repo markets and the pass through of
monetary policy to prices. In addition, an increased demand for safe assets from
stablecoin issuers could also affect monetary policy space by reducing the free-float of
securities available for monetary policy operations (i.e. purchases under quantitative
easing programmes or collateral in credit operations). However, under reasonably
plausible calibration scenarios (i.e. where a limited share of potential users adopt
stablecoins), the impact on risk-free rates of the additional demand for
euro-denominated safe assets is estimated to be limited. Furthermore, an increased
37
By contrast, if a stablecoin issuer had direct access to the central banks balance sheet, it would be akin
to a narrow bank and its reserves would be sufficient to redeem any withdrawals.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
21
demand for euro-denominated safe assets could also strengthen the international role
of the euro and bring economic benefits.
38
4.1.5 Exchange rate channel
An extensive use of stablecoins in the second scenario could affect the
exchange rate channel of monetary policy and might make it more difficult for
monetary policy to control domestic developments, as in the case of dollarised
countries. In the case of multi-currency stablecoins, the exchange rate channel might
be affected given that the euro is a global reserve currency and is therefore likely to be
included in stablecoin currency baskets. If a multi-currency stablecoin were to be used
as an invoicing currency, relative prices would be less affected by domestic monetary
policy.
39
At the same time, prices could be affected by foreign monetary policy or
exchange rate shocks. However, the likelihood of multi-currency stablecoins, such as
multi-currency Libra, becoming invoicing currencies is estimated to be low.
Specifically, internal analyses indicate that, under plausible assumptions regarding
Libra’s potential use as an international invoicing currency
40
, the pass through of euro
exchange rate movements to import prices would hardly change. In turn, the
exchange rate pass through would be stronger if invoicing in Libra accounted for a
significantly larger share of euro area imports than assumed above. However, in that
case holdings of Libra per user would rise to much larger and possibly economically
implausible levels. At the same time, the euro area economy might become more
exposed to shocks in the value of stablecoins like multi-currency Libra, arising for
example from changes in the value of one of the currencies in the basket. Shocks
affecting the value of stablecoins collateralised by euro would transmit more directly to
the euro area by affecting the purchasing power of the stablecoin holders. In a more
extreme scenario, “digital currency areas
41
might arise (characterised as a global
network of payments and transactions in a specific stablecoin), which could increase
the international comovement of macroeconomic developments and affect the
cross-border transmission of monetary policy. This might make it more challenging for
monetary policy to stabilise domestic economic developments.
4.1.6 Monetary policy operations
The monetary policy implications outlined above could affect the size of the
Eurosystem’s balance sheet and its structure. This impact would be especially
pronounced under the third scenario where stablecoins are not only used for
payments but also as a store of value. A reduced demand for banknotes and central
38
These benefits include, among others, lower transaction and hedging costs for trading internationally for
euro area household and companies, seigniorage, and being able to issue debt at lower interest rates
(exorbitant privilege”).
39
Single-currency stablecoins on the other hand should not carry major implications for the exchange-rate
channel.
40
The assumptions are that (i) euro accounts for 30% of the basket of currencies backing Libra (which is
close to the share of the euro in the SDR basket), and (ii) Libra is used as invoicing currency for 5% of
euro area imports about the combined shares of the renminbi and yen in global payments.
41
See Brunnermeier and Niepelt (2019).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
22
bank reserves, which could be the case already in the second scenario, would lead to
a smaller balance sheet and less seigniorage income. If in addition stablecoins were
used as a store of value, this would increase the demand for safe assets as outlined in
Section 4.1.4. In turn, this could lead to scarcity of eligible assets for central bank
policy operations such as asset purchases and open market operations.
42
In addition,
risks arising from traditional counterparties could increase if the use of stablecoins had
financial stability implications for the banking system. If the risk of financial instability
increased beyond the traditional banking sector, the central bank might consider
interacting with a wider range of counterparties. Financial stability issues will be
discussed in the following section.
4.2 Financial stability
Both fragilities within the stablecoin arrangement and the interconnectedness
with the financial systems represent sources of financial stability risks. As the
G7 report on global stablecoins and the FSB consultative document on the regulatory,
supervisory and oversight challenges of global stablecoin arrangements
43
have
already analysed and identified a vast array of financial stability risks from stablecoin
arrangements, the following paragraphs will focus on the two most prominent risks:
risk of a liquidity “run” impairing the functioning of the stablecoin arrangement, and risk
of contagion to the wider financial system emanating from an impaired stablecoin
arrangement.
44
4.2.1 Liquidity run
The value of stablecoins may be exposed to risks inherent in the investment in
non-zero risk financial assets such as credit, liquidity, market and foreign
exchange (FX) risks. An important question from a financial stability perspective is:
who ultimately bears the investment risks? If the stablecoin arrangement does not
guarantee any fixed value of the stablecoin, this will move in tandem with the value of
the “collateral” (see Section 2). In this case, the end user is the bearer of all risks and
the stablecoin is equivalent in substance to a fund share with the price equal to the
fund’s net asset value. There is no solvency risk for such an arrangement as it is akin
to a “pass through” structure.
Runs on the stablecoin arrangement could occur if end users lose confidence
in the issuer or its network. This could happen, for example, if an adverse event
occurs (such as a cyberattack to the system or theft from wallet) or if end users realise
that the collateral assets are losing value, thereby casting doubts on the value of the
stablecoin. Such a realisation could trigger substantial redemptions of stablecoins
which could be amplified to the extent that end users misconceive stablecoin holdings
as a substitute of bank deposits.
42
By contrast, if stablecoins kept the collateral in central bank reserves, this could lead to an expansion of
the balance sheet.
43
See Financial Stability Board (2020).
44
For more detailed discussion, see Adachi et al. (2020).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
23
Runs could also occur when the stablecoin arrangement guarantees a fixed
value of the stablecoin (e.g. some tokenised funds). In this case, any losses
stemming from its investment are borne by the stablecoin issuer (or whoever provides
such guarantees), including losses from exchange rate fluctuations if relevant.
Therefore, confidence in the stablecoin and its arrangement depends critically on the
loss absorption capacity of the guarantor and doubt thereof could trigger a run on the
stablecoin arrangement. (By implication, applicable regulatory requirements have to
be sufficiently comprehensive to addressing complex and interrelated risks posed by
the stablecoin arrangement.)
4.2.2 Contagion effects
In the event of a run on a stablecoin with the scale envisaged in the second and
third scenarios, the liquidation of assets to cover redemptions could have
negative contagion effects on the financial system. It should be noted that shocks
to the stablecoin arrangement in emerging markets with weak institutional capacity
(such as operational incidents) could spill-back to advanced economies in which the
pool of collateral assets mostly reside. Moreover, some components of the stablecoin
arrangement (e.g. designated dealers) may stop their function in a manner similar to
that observed in the 2007 global financial crisis when securitisation vehicles
redemptions were suspended.
Short-term government debt markets would be most profoundly affected in
such scenarios. As the stablecoin arrangement might represent a significant investor
in the short-term government debt market, runs on it would translate to large price
volatility and illiquidity spikes. In addition, the stability of bank funding may be
weakened as stablecoin holders may have moved funds from bank deposits to global
stablecoins, creating a banking system in which sticky retail deposits are replaced with
institutional deposits as noted in Section 4.1.2.
Banks would be affected through multiple channels in a run: those banks which
have received the arrangement’s collateral could experience a sudden deposit
withdrawal as noted above; those engaged in the arrangement as actors (designated
dealers, third-party trading platforms, etc.) could be subject to associated market
volatility and also with reputational risks for their role.
4.3 Market infrastructures and payments
The core transfer function of a stablecoin arrangement, regardless of the
design of the technical platform (e.g. centralised versus decentralised), can be
characterised as a payment system (see Section 2).
45
Therefore, like other
payment systems, stablecoin arrangements that are not properly managed can be a
source of large-scale disruption and even systemic risk in the second and third
scenarios.
45
Certain stablecoin arrangements may also undertake functions of other financial market infrastructures
(e.g. central securities depositorie s).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
24
Separately from their core transfer function, stablecoin arrangements also
incorporate a function to provide end users with a means of payment similar to
payment schemes. While payment schemes do not give rise to systemic risk
concerns, their orderly functioning facilitates secure and effective payment
instruments that meet users’ needs and are critical for maintaining public trust in the
euro.
4.3.1 Risks posed and borne by stablecoin arrangements in their transfer
function
The multiplicity of functions and entities involved in stablecoin arrangements
raises questions around governance. On the one hand, the involvement of a large
spectrum of stakeholders supports the consideration of diverse market interests and
views. On the other hand, a highly complex governance structure could hamper the
decision-making process pertaining to the arrangements design and technological
evolution or by slowing incident responses related to operational issues. Furthermore,
arrangements that rely on intermediaries and third-party providers also bear risks
from, and pose risks to, these entities. Clear and transparent governance is all the
more important for arrangements that operate in multiple jurisdictions and/or currency
areas as envisaged in global retail stablecoin initiatives.
Stablecoin arrangements that use DLT incur the potential benefits and
drawbacks inherent in any distributed setup in terms of operational reliability
and resilience. Benefits of using multiple synchronised ledgers and multiple
processing nodes include reducing the risk from a single point-of-failure. At the same
time, any arrangement operated by many parties is more prone to cyber risk since it
has a larger attack surface. In this regard, cryptographic tools play a critical role in
ensuring the security and confidentiality of information stored on the distributed ledger.
Furthermore, distributed ledgers are inherently more complex and potentially
resource-intensive to operate compared to traditional systems.
Stablecoin arrangements operating in a cross-jurisdictional context and/or on a
global scale may pose specific risks such as heightened legal risk. Uncertainties
regarding the applicable law and/or the competent court(s) in case of disputes may
result in conflict-of-law issues. This is in addition to the complexities around the legal
and regulatory classification of the asset and the mapping of an arrangement’s
function to the domestic legal and regulatory framework outlined in Section 2 and the
discussion around the legal underpinning of arrangements based on DLT in some
jurisdictions e.g. regarding the ownership or transfer of assets, and settlement finality.
4.3.2 Implications for Eurosystem oversight
Preliminary analysis
46
suggests that the CPMI-IOSCO PFMI provide a sufficient
basis for authorities to assess the systemic importance of stablecoin
46
See Annex 4 of Financial Stability Board (2020).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
25
arrangements, to ensure their safety and efficiency, and to cooperate with other
relevant authorities. While the CPMI-IOSCO has identified no need for an
amendment of the PFMI at this time, the application of PFMI to stablecoin
arrangements may require further guidance regarding the interpretation of current
requirements in the light of the specificities of stablecoin arrangements.
The PFMI provide guidance for relevant authorities to assess the systemic
importance of payment systems which, complemented by the qualitative and
quantitative factors identified by the relevant authorities, could also inform the
assessment of the systemic importance of stablecoin arrangements for the
purpose of PFMI application. The regulation of the ECB on oversight requirements
for SIPS sets quantitative criteria for the assessment of systemic importance.
The entities involved in the transfer function of a stablecoin arrangement could
be subject to the Eurosystem’s oversight. A decision in this respect would consider
the qualification of the asset/activity under EU regulation. For example, if an asset
qualifies as e-money and its issuer is supervised according to EMD2, it is likely that the
respective arrangement qualifies as a payment scheme under the Eurosystem’s
oversight framework. The respective arrangement could still be subject to oversight as
a (proxy to) payment system (provided the criteria outlined in Section 2 were fulfilled)
and/or payment scheme.
As the criteria for the identification of a SIPS are linked to the activity of clearing
and settling euro-denominated payments, the SIPS regulation might not apply
to stablecoin arrangements that handle payments denominated in another
currency or unit of account, yet the system could be subject to the general
payment system oversight framework. In fact, the Eurosystem oversight policy
framework is not limited to systems that clear and settle euro-denominated payments.
The Eurosystem would still be in a position to apply the PFMI, or a subset thereof, to a
non-euro-denominated system that is located in the euro area even though the system
is not subject to the SIPS regulation.
Stablecoin arrangements could also qualify as payment schemes (see
Section 2). The ongoing review of the Eurosystem oversight framework for payment
instruments and schemes should ensure that payment schemes based on stablecoins
that are denominated in, funded by or collateralised by euro, fall under oversight. It is
further noted that, in the event that a stablecoin arrangement qualifies as a payment
scheme, but not as a payment system, the clearing and settlement function of the
arrangement could be regarded as an associated function of the scheme and be
subject to oversight.
Stablecoin arrangements that settle euro-denominated transactions may
warrant the application of the Eurosystem’s location policy. If a stablecoin
arrangement were to reach a certain threshold
47
, it would have to be operationally and
legally located in the euro area under such policy. For other offshore payment systems
47
The location policy requirement applies to all payment systems that either settle more than €5 billion per
day, or account for more than 0.2% of the total daily average value of payment transactions processed by
euro area interbank funds transfer systems which provide for final settlement in central bank money
(whichever of the two amounts is higher).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
26
settling euro-denominated transactions or payment systems with significant
funding/defunding in euro, the Eurosystem would seek cooperative oversight.
48
In
case banks are used to execute economic functions of a stablecoin arrangement, the
already established supervisory arrangements for cross-border coordination will be
employed and amended, if need be, according to the specific arrangement.
Stablecoin arrangements established outside of the EU should be subject to
international cooperative oversight arrangements comprising all relevant
authorities that have a legitimate interest. Responsibility E of the PFMI (together
with the Lamfalussy principles for offshore payment systems
49
) provides a strong
basis for such cooperation, and allows for the involvement of other relevant regulatory
and supervisory authorities if deemed necessary. As an example, the Swiss
authorities created the “Libra College” for the oversight of Libra in which the ECB was
invited to take part. It is, however, noted that the Eurosystem would have no legal
means to enforce such cooperation but would rely on moral suasion (name and
shame).
4.3.3 Implications for the retail payments market
Stablecoins of the types described in the second scenario may alter the current
retail payments landscape in Europe and globally. Both the international payments
landscape with relatively slow and costly cross-currency transfers and a
fragmented European retail payments market (e.g. in the front-end of instant payment
solutions at the point of interaction) provide opportunities for stablecoins to meet
users demand in terms of speed, affordability, access or convenience. Some
initiatives (e.g. Libra) can leverage existing consumer platforms to maximise user
convenience and expedite take-up (e.g. through incentives). This might affect the level
playing field in payment services and contribute to increasing Europe’s dependence
on global players in the area of payments.
Stablecoin arrangements may also pose concerns for EU market integration
and interoperability. Stablecoin arrangements may fall outside of the scope of SEPA
Regulation that harmonises the way cashless euro payments are made across Europe
and mandates interoperability. While a stablecoin initiative such as Libra may de facto
ensure pan-European coverage, pan-European reachability (intended as all
consumers having the ability to make payments at the national and EU level under the
same conditions) may require a deliberate effort. Furthermore, in the event of multiple
stablecoin arrangements, fragmentation may occur across the arrangements
networks. From a demand side perspective, users may face trade-offs between
convenience on the one hand and additional costs (e.g. cash-out and other fees, idle
balances) and switching barriers on the other hand.
48
With regard to oversight of cross-border FMIs, Responsibility E of Committee on Payments and Market
Infrastructures and the International Organisation of Securities Commissions (2020) foresees
cooperation with other authorities at international level where appropriate. Cross-border cooperation
among relevant authorities is typically initiated by the authority of the system’s home jurisdiction. The
authority of the home jurisdiction usually has the primary responsibility for the oversight of the system.
49
See Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (1990).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
27
4.3.4 Implications on the use of euro banknotes for payments
In the second and third scenarios, stablecoins are likely to coexist with ca sh in
payment transactions. This is due to the unique characteristics of cash being
physical while stablecoins will primarily compete with other electronic means of
payment at least in a short/medium term. Even in a scenario where stablecoins satisfy
the demand for storing value, they are likely to coexist with euro banknotes. This
applies also to the demand from outside the euro area. There, in fact, euro banknotes
are often held by people who do not trust the currency or banking system in their own
countries, and trust instead an international currency, especially in physical form, i.e.
cash. It is hardly imaginable that in such situations people will store their last resort
assets in a digital form. It is estimated that about 30% of the total euro banknotes
demand originates from outside the euro area.
4.4 Banking supervision and prudential regulation
The possible involvement of supervised institutions in stablecoin
arrangements would both support the materialisation of scenarios in which
stablecoins effectively fulfil a payment and/or store of value function and have
manifold implications for the these institutions. A role for banks in these situations
would reflect on ECB supervision and the adequacy of prudential regulatory treatment
of emerging assets.
4.4.1 Possible roles of SSM banks in stablecoin arrangements
A stablecoin arrangement may rely on banks to ensure its orderly functioning.
50
SSM banks could take up a variety of roles in stablecoin arrangements to facilitate the
creation, redemption, circulation and use of stablecoins. They could fulfil three broad
types of non-mutually exclusive roles in a generic stablecoin arrangement to support
its core functions (stabilisation, transfer, user interaction) also taking into account
jurisdictional restrictions.
1. Provision of various services to the stablecoin arrangements stabilisation
function, as e.g. (i) members of the governance body of stablecoin arrangement
who share the responsibility of managing its assets; (ii) custodians of collateral
assets; (iii) asset managers; (iv) prime brokers. In the secondary market, banks
could act as market makers on exchanges, or exchanges per se, thereby helping
to stabilise the price of the stablecoin. They could also support a stablecoin
arrangements stabilisation function indirectly by e.g.: (i) receiving deposits from
the stablecoin arrangement, likely to interest-bearing accounts or
50
According to Financial Stability Board (2020), in some jurisdictions stablecoin arrangements already
deposit funds at major banks. This has the potential to: (i) create an additional layer of intermediation
between households and banks; (ii) reduce the stability of bank funding in stress conditions; (iii) impact
the functioning and resilience for the financial markets (e.g. short-term government bonds) in which
reserve funds are invested (see also Sections 4.1 and 4.2). Currently these risks are likely small given the
small scale of existing stablecoin arrangements compared to the balance sheets of major banks.
However, there are limited data to assess such bank exposures.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
28
securities/investments; (ii) selling assets (e.g. short-term government securities)
to the stablecoin arrangement; (iii) providing FX c onversion services; (iv) offering
hedging services, e.g. via derivatives, or market access to such services with
other third parties.
2. Operation of a validating node in the DLT transfer mechanism.
3. Facilitation of the stablecoin arrangements interaction with users, as
e.g. providers of custodian wallets and payment services in stablecoins.
Banks role in stablecoin arrangements could also go beyond supporting the
core functions, as they could benefit from synergies via the offer of additional
services. For example, banks could take deposits and extend credit in stablecoins,
including via fractional reserve banking. There could be new forms of cross-selling,
such as offering certain financial services or products exclusively to stablecoin users
or at preferential rates. Furthermore, custodian wallets might be linked with other
financial services (e.g. payment account aggregation services) and create a demand
for stablecoin ATMs and merchant acceptance services. Finally, if global stablecoins
fostered greater access, they could trigger demand for additional bank services.
Banks could be subject to a wide range of risks through the provision of such
services, such as governance, liquidity, market, credit, operational and
technological, legal and compliance risks. Governance risk may arise from banks
lack of understanding of the risks of stablecoins and impaired ability to engage in
effective risk assessment and decision-making and to establish adequate controls.
Banks that receive deposits from stablecoin arrangements could be exposed to
funding risk, whereas banks-resellers are subject to market liquidity risks in situations
of loss of confidence in the stablecoin. Changes in the valuation and pricing of holding
of stablecoins could be a source of risks for banks engaging in trading, dealing, and
market making. Credit risk ranges from intraday exposures to loss of equity in the
event that the project fails. A stablecoin arrangements endpoints could be subject to
cyberattacks, leading to e.g. private keys held by banks being stolen. Stablecoin
arrangements may experience operational issues with reputational and legal
implications also for banks. Finally, banks that undertake activities in a stablecoin
arrangement or the broader ecosystem will need to consider the application of
regulatory framework to their businesses.
Providing financial services to a stablecoin arrangement or within the broader
stablecoin ecosystem might not be a profitable strategy for banks in the long
run. Especially on initiatives sponsored by large technology companies, the
proliferation of innovative products and services may not be sustainable if returns do
not outweigh the increased operational complexity and the loss of direct access to
transactional data flows that banks would otherwise accumulate and use to their
business advantage.
Banks may also face increased competition. In the second scenario (“new
payment method”), stablecoins could exert pressure on commissions and fees
charged by banks for payments and transfers. Increased competition may also erode
revenues that banks currently obtain from the payment card business.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
29
4.4.2 Supervisory powers
Activities undertaken by SSM banks in the context of stablecoin arrangements
(see Section 4.4.1) would not constitute regulated financial services pursuant to
current EU law but ratherother business activities of credit institutions.
Crypto-asset (bitcoin-like) related activities also fall under this category.
Even if stablecoin-related activities of credit institutions fall outside of the
scope of regulated activities, supervisors have available a range of supervisory
powers in the Capital Requirements Directive (CRD IV)
51
that could provide a
tool to mitigate relevant risks. In detail, in carrying out other business activities, as
mentioned in Article 74 of CRD IV on internal governance, credit institutions must have
in place appropriate arrangements to mitigate the operational (including IT) and
reputational risks involved. In any case, other powers may also be available under the
national laws (e.g. to prohibit other business activities not linked to the carrying out of
regulated financial services where this activity could impair the financial soundness of
the firm concerned).
52
The same could apply for CRD IV Article 97 (supervisory
review and evaluation process) and Article 104 (supervisory powers).
Further, the EBA Guidelines on internal governance under Directive
2013/36/EU
53
as well as the EBA Guidelines on outsourcing arrangements
54
could be relevant. Supervisors may need to assess governance issues that banks
face when entering stablecoin arrangements, as well as the sufficiency of qualified
staff in all three lines of defence. Moreover, contractual agreement should comply with
the regulatory framework and the right to audit should be warranted for both the bank
and the supervisors. Banks should also include specific clauses, as appropriate,
ensuring the continuity of operations in case the institution were to face resolution.
As a best practice, the assessment should always take place on a case-by-case
basis, taking into account the specifics of each arrangement. The main focus
should be the assessment of potential risks that such activities involve, while
maintaining a technology-neutral position.
4.4.3 Prudential/accounting treatment
In general, apart from the appropriate risk management framework previously
mentioned, the risks inherent in stablecoins will have to be captured in a very
51
Directive 2013/36/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2013 on access to the
activity of credit institutions and the prudential supervision of credit institutions and investment firms,
amending Directive 2002/87/EC and repealing Directives 2006/48/EC and 2006/49/EC ( OJ L 176,
27.6.2013, p. 338).
52
The EBA has highlighted multiple times via warnings and opinions the risks (especially money laundering
and terrorist financing) arising from two emerging forms of activity involving crypto-assets:
(1) crypto-asset trading, usually through digital platforms operated by providers engaged in exchange
services between crypto-assets and fiat currencies or other crypto-assets (e.g. the exchange of virtual
currencies such as bitcoin or Ethereum), and (2) custodian wallet provision (services to safeguard/store
private cryptographic keys granting rights to access and transfer crypto-asse ts).
53
European Banking Authority (2017).
54
European Banking Authority (2019b).
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
30
conservative manner via Pillar 1 or even supplemented by Pillar 2 requirements,
if necessary.
In its analysis on crypto-assets, the ICA-TF concluded that the regulation on
prudential requirements for credit institutions (CRR
55
), as it currently stands, is
not tailored to crypto-assets with high volatility and advocated a common
conservative prudential treatment for crypto-assets. The ICA-TF favoured Pillar 1
full deduction from CET1 similarly to other assets classified as “intangible assets
under the accounting framework. The ECB position is aligned with the international
standard-setters, in particular the Basel Committee for Banking Supervision (BCBS).
The BCBS has issued a discussion paper
56
seeking stakeholders’ views on the
prudential/accounting regulatory treatment of crypto-assets. Regarding stablecoins, it
is of the view that these assets warrant further assessment and elaboration before
specifying a prudential treatment.
According to CRR Article 24, the valuation of assets and off-balance sheet
items shall be effected in accordance with the applicable accounting
framework. Therefore, should a bank hold stablecoins, the prudential treatment
(particularly from a solvency and liquidity perspective) will depend on the IFRS
classification of stablecoins as, among other things: cash or cash equivalent (IAS 32),
other financial instrument (IAS 32), inventory (IAS 2), intangible asset (IAS 38 as for
crypto-assets in the ECB recommendation). Discussions around the accounting
classification of stablecoins are still ongoing and might ultimately differ from
crypto-assets due to the different features of these assets, e.g. lower volatility
57
or
collateral. A different accounting treatment under the current regulatory framework
also automatically results in a different prudential treatment. Even if full deductions
under Pillar 1 do not apply, supervisory considerations in the context of the Pillar 2
framework could still be applied, subject to their risks and according to their materiality
following the principle of proportionality.
As some of the ECB supervised institutions might in the future be materially
exposed to stablecoin initiatives, it is important that a prudential treatment is
developed as soon as possible. CRR provisions will have to be applied to these
entities operating in the EU and the risks inherent to stablecoins will have to be
captured either via Pillar 1 or Pillar 2, as well as by adopting the appropriate risk
management frameworks. A timely prudential treatment could prevent banks from
accumulating exposures in a prudential void.
55
Regulation (EU) No 575/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2013 on
prudential requirements for credit institutions and investment firms and amending Regulation
No 648/2012 (OJ L 176, 27.6.2013, p. 1).
56
See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2019).
57
According to Bullmann et al. (2019), the average volatility, expressed as the annualised average
seven-day standard deviation of daily returns between 27 December 2017 (the earliest date when all
three stablecoins considered were traded) and 28 July 2019 was 10% for Tether USD, 27% for Dai and
37% for NuBits (now defunct). The same measure of volatility applied to the five crypto-assets wi th
highest market capitalisation in the same period gave values of 69% for Bitcoin, 91% for Ether, 100% for
XRP, 117% for Bitcoin Cash, and 96% for Litecoin. See also Section 3, Chart 4.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
31
5 Conclusions
The term “stablecoinmay be perceived to have positive connotations in terms
of stablecoins intrinsic stability and usability as a form of money but these
features are neither intrinsic to, nor a prerogative of, stablecoins in and of
themselves instead they can be attained only through appropriate design and
effective risk management. As regulatory principles are established and approaches
are defined, the term “stablecoin” should be replaced by a choice of terminology to
shift the emphasis away from the issuer’s promise of stability.
The implications of stablecoins for monetary policy, financial stability, market
infrastructure and payments, and banking supervision depend on the specific
scenario for the uptake of stablecoins as a result of their concrete features and
EU user demand. Of all scenarios, stablecoins as an alternative store of value is
currently the most remote since stablecoin arrangements through collateralisation will
not be exempted from a low rate environment. Besides, deposits and cash have
proved resilient to existing alternatives. That said, the uptake in other currency areas
of stablecoins collateralised with euro-denominated assets could have implications on
the Eurosystem’s monetary policy transmission, which are beyond its control.
Under more plausible scenarios, the Eurosystem has a range of instruments at
its disposal to manage the impact of stablecoins on its mandate and tasks. The
Eurosystems oversight framework will cover stablecoin arrangements that qualify as
payment systems, regardless of the technology used and organisational setup.
Furthermore, stablecoin arrangements that set standardised and common rules for
the execution of payment transactions between end users may fall under the oversight
framework for payment instruments and schemes, which is currently in the being
revised. From a banking supervision perspective, competent authorities have a range
of supervisory powers (based on CRD articles) that can be applied to mitigate the risks
stemming from stablecoin-related activities of supervised institutions. Banks should
put in place an appropriate risk management framework commensurate to their role in
stablecoin arrangements.
The application of these tools needs to be underpinned by adequate,
internationally coordinated regulation and cooperative oversight. The general
principle “same business, same risks, same rules” should guide regulatory efforts to
ensure a level playing field and prevent regulatory arbitrage. Further work may be
necessary for international standard setting bodies to address emerging risks. This
may include, for example, developing an appropriate accounting and prudential
treatment. Given the global nature of stablecoin arrangements, an EU regulatory
approach cannot be developed in isolation, but should be informed by ongoing efforts
of standard setting bodies. In this respect, the effective oversight and supervision of
stablecoin arrangements that span multiple jurisdictions requires relevant authorities
to collaborate under the umbrella of international cooperative oversight arrangements.
The Eurosystem continues monitoring the evolution of the stablecoins market
to be able to respond to rapid changes in all possible scenarios. Eurosystem
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
32
action aims to be commensurate to the risks identified, and to preserve public policy
priorities as needed while enabling private sector initiatives to safely extract the most
value from technological innovations, to the benefit of a wide range of users. In
parallel, this task may entail fostering central bank innovations to cater for a changed
environment in the payment space and altered conditions for the exercise of a central
banks core mandate.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
33
References
Adachi, M. Cominetta, M., Kaufmann, C. and van der Kraaij, A. (2020), “A regulatory
and financial stability perspective on global stablecoins”, Macroprudential Bulletin,
Issue 10, ECB, Frankfurt am Main, March.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2019), Discussion paper Designing a
prudential treatment for crypto-assets, Bank for International Settlements, December.
Blockdata (2019) Stablecoins An overview of the current state of stablecoins, June.
Brunnermeier, M. K., and Niepelt, D. (2019), “On the Equivalence of Private and Public
Money”, Working Paper Series, No. 25877, NBER, Cambridge, May.
Bullmann D., Klemm, J. and Pinna, A. (2019), In search for stability in crypto-assets:
are stablecoins the solution?”, Occasional Paper Series, No 230, ECB, August.
Coin Metrics (2020) “Weekly Feature: The Rise of Stablecoins, Coin Metrics State of
the Network, Issue 59 Weekly Feature, published online; last accessed 15 September
2020.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (1990), Report of the Committee
on Interbank Netting Schemes of the central banks of the Group of Ten countries
(Lamfalussy Report), CPMI Papers, Bank for International Settlements, November.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (2019), Wholesale digital
tokens, CPMI Papers, No 190, Bank for International Settlements, December.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures and the International
Organisation of Securities Commissions (2012), “Principles for financial market
infrastructures”, CPMI Papers, No 101, Bank for International Settlements, April.
Council of the European Union (2019), Joint statement by the Council and the
Commission on "stablecoins, published online, last accessed 15 September 2020.
ECB Crypto-Assets Task Force (2019), “Crypto-Assets: Implications for financial
stability, monetary policy, and payments and market infrastructures”, Occasional
Paper Series, No 223, ECB, Frankfurt am Main, May.
European Banking Authority (2019a), Report with advice for the European
Commission on crypto-assets, January.
European Banking Authority (2019b), Final Report on EBA Guidelines on outsourcing
arrangements, February.
European Banking Authority (2017), Final Report Guidelines on internal governance
under Directive 2013/36/EU, September.
ECB Occasional Paper Series No 247 / September 2020
34
European Central Bank (2019),Stablecoins no coins, but are they stable?”, In
Focus, No. 3, November.
European System of Central Banks (2020), European System of Central Banks
(ESCB) response to the European Commission’s public consultation on EU framework
for markets in crypto-assets, ECB, Frankfurt am Main, April, published online, last
accessed 15 September 2020.
Financial Stability Board (2020), addressing the regulatory, supervisory and oversight
challenges raised by “global stablecoin” arrangements Consultative document, April.
G7 Working Group on Stablecoins (2019), Investigating the Impact of Global
Stablecoins, October.
Libra Association (2020), White Paper v2.0, published online, last accessed
15 September 2020.
Acknowledgements
This paper w as prepared under the umbrella of the ECB Internal Crypto-Assets Task Force (ICA-TF).
Chair of the ICA-TF
Fiona van Echelpoel
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Fiona.van_Echelpoel@ecb.europa.eu
Secretariat of the ICA-TF
Maria Teresa Chimienti
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Maria_Teresa.Chimienti@ecb.europa.eu
Members of the ICA-TF
Mitsutoshi Adachi
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Mitsutoshi.Adachi@ecb.europa.eu
Phoebus Athanassiou
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Phoebus.Athanassiou@ecb.europa.eu
Irina Balteanu
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Irina.Balteanu@ecb.europa.eu
Thomas Barkias
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Thomas.Barkias@ecb.europa.eu
Ioannis Ganoulis
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Ioannis.Ganoulis@ecb.europa.eu
Danielle Kedan
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Danielle.Kedan@ecb.europa.eu
Holger Neuhaus
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Holger.Neuhaus@ecb.europa.eu
Adam Pawlikowski
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Adam.Paw likow ski@ecb.europa.eu
Günther Philipp
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Guenther.Philipp@ecb.int
Raphael Poignet
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Raphael.Poignet@ecb.europa.eu
Stephan Sauer
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Stephan.Sauer@ecb.europa.eu
Doris Schneeberger
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Doris.Schneeberger@ecb.europa.eu
Jens Tapking
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Jens.Tapking@ecb.europa.eu
Colm Toolin
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: Colm.Toolin@ecb.europa.eu
This paper benefited from contributions by: Katrin Assenmacher, Dirk Bullmann, Ludovico Cardone, Adrien Delcroix, Christoph
Kaufmann, Stefan Kromolicki, Carolina López-Quiles, Urszula Kochanska, Klaus Löber, Agnieszka Mazany, Panagiotis Papapaschalis,
Andrea Pinna, Ignacio Terol.
© European Central Bank, 2020
Postal address 60640 Frankfurt am Main, Germany
Telephone +49 69 1344 0
Website www.ecb.europa.eu
All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, w hether printed or produced
electronically, in w hole or in part, is permitted only w ith the explicit w ritten authorisation of the ECB or the authors.
This paper can be downloaded without charge from the ECB w ebsite, from the Social Science Research Network electronic library or from
RePEc: Research Papers in Economics. Information on all of the papers published in the ECB Occasional Paper Series can be found on
the ECB’s w ebsite.
PDF ISBN 978-92-899-4253-9, ISSN 1725-6534, doi:10.2866/822388, QB-AQ-20-010-EN-N