TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
Presented to the Houses of Parliament pursuant to section 77 of the
Deregulation Act 2015
July 2015
©Crown copyright 2015
We can also provide documents to meet the specific requirements for people with disabilities.
Please email en[email protected].gov.uk
Department for Culture, Media & Sport
Printed in the UK on recycled paper
You may re-use this information (excluding logos) free of charge in any
format or medium, under the terms of the Open Government Licence.
To view this licence, visit http://www.nationalarchives.gov.uk/doc/
open-government-licence/ or e-mail: psi@nationalarchives.gsi.gov.uk.
Where we have identified any third party copyright information you will
need to obtain permission from the copyright holders concerned.
Any enquiries regarding this document should be sent to us at
enquiries@culture.gsi.gov.uk
This document is also available from our website at www.gov.uk/dcms
Print ISBN 9781474122078
Web ISBN 9781474122085
ID 16061503 07/15
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
2
Contents
Foreword 3
Executive Summary 5
Chapter 1: Introduction and Background to the Review 9
Chapter 2: Current Law and Enforcement Regime 14
Chapter 3: Consultation Options 22
3a. Option 1 - Retain the Current Criminal Enforcement System 23
3b. Option 2 - Reform of current system 34
3c. Option 3 - Out-of-court settlement 48
3d. Option 4 - Fixed Monetary Penalty 56
3e. Option 5 - Civil Monetary Penalty 64
3f. Option 6 - Civil Debt 71
Chapter 4: Other options for change 76
Chapter 5: Conclusions and Next Steps 79
Annexes
A: Terms of Reference 81
B: Cost-Benefit Analysis 82
C: Jurisdictional Differences 101
D: Summary of Legal Framework 102
E: Analysis of Key Evidence 107
F: Summary of Consultation Process and Responses Received 112
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
3
Foreword
In October 2014, I was appointed by the Secretary of State to undertake an independent review of the
enforcement regime for television licence evasion. Under the law as it currently stands, the installation
or use of a television receiver without a licence is an offence under section 363 of the Communications
Act 2003. The offence is punishable by way of a fine up to a maximum of £1000. Concerns about the
operation of the criminal offence have been expressed in Parliament and elsewhere. The importance
attached to these concerns is evidenced by the enactment of section 77 of the Deregulation Act 2015,
which imposed a duty on the Secretary of State to review the criminal enforcement of licence fee
evasion and to consider proposals for reform, including possible decriminalisation.
This is not the first time that this complex issue has received detailed consideration. In his Review of
the Criminal Courts of England and Wales (2001), Sir Robin Auld recommended that the use of a
television without a licence should remain a criminal offence, but that it should be dealt with in the first
instance by a fixed penalty notice, discounted for prompt purchase of a licence and payment of penalty,
and subject to the defendant’s right to dispute guilt in court. This recommendation was considered by
the Home Office and a number of drawbacks to such a fixed penalty scheme were identified (chiefly
that it might lead to an increase in evasion and be costly to implement).
More recently, in February 2015, the House of Commons Select Committee Report ‘Future of the BBC’
criticised the criminal offence as anachronistic and out of proportion with responses to non-payment for
services such as gas, electricity and water, but concluded that decriminalisation was not feasible under
the current system of licence fee collection.
Following a lengthy process of review, during which I have been assisted by a wide range of individuals
and organisations, I have concluded that, in the overall public interest, the current system of criminal
enforcement should be maintained, at least while the method of licence fee collection remains in its
present form. Any significant change to the current system of enforcement, including a move towards
decriminalisation, carries the risk of an increase in evasion and would involve significant cost to the
taxpayer and those who pay the licence fee. While my principal conclusion is that the current system
of criminal deterrence and prosecution should be maintained, I have, where possible, made
suggestions for improvements to be made.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
4
It is significant that this Review has taken place shortly in advance of an in-depth review of the BBC’s
Royal Charter. The Charter Review will look in detail at the BBC’s operations, as well as the mechanism
for collecting the licence fee. I recognise in this report that any change to the method of licence fee
collection is likely to have an impact on the viability of introducing a non-criminal scheme of
enforcement. It is to be hoped that the recommendations and observations made in this report will be
of assistance to those involved in the Charter Review.
During the course of the Review I received unfailingly courteous and encouraging support from officials
in the Department for Culture, Media and Sport. The Review Team comprised Sophie Marment,
Genevieve Mitchell, Dan Lihou, Tessa Gilder-Smith, Vivek Kumar and Lawrence Bird. To each of them
I owe an enormous debt of gratitude.
The views expressed in this Report are my own.
David Perry QC
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
5
Executive Summary
A television licence is required to watch live or nearly live broadcast television content on any electronic
device in the United Kingdom. Responsibility for collecting the licence fee lies with the BBC, which
operates under the trading name TV Licensing.
1
Section 363 of the Communications Act 2003 provides that a person who installs or uses a television
receiver without being authorised by a licence is guilty of an offence. The offence is punishable by way
of a fine up to a maximum of £1000.
This report considers whether the sanctions currently in place for TV licence evasion are appropriate
and fair, and whether the regime represents good value for licence fee payers and taxpayers.
The obligation to conduct a review of the sanctions regime is contained in section 77 of the Deregulation
Act 2015. Section 77 was enacted as a result of concerns expressed by Parliamentarians and others
that the criminal nature of the current regime represents a disproportionate response to the problem of
licence fee evasion. Section 77, among other things, requires this Review to “examine proposals for
decriminalisation of offences under section 363”.
The Review’s objectives were identified in the Terms of Reference:
To examine whether the sanctions for contravening this offence are appropriate, fair,
and whether the regime represents value for money for licence fee payers and
taxpayers.
To identify and assess options for amending the current enforcement regime, including
those for decriminalisation of TV licensing offences, and whether these options would
represent an improvement, based on a number of key considerations (set out below).
To make recommendations to the Government by the end of June 2015.
The key considerations were identified as follows:
a. Value for money for licence fee payers and taxpayers in enforcement of the failure to
have a TV licence, including operational, revenue and investment costs of the
enforcement regime to the BBC and to the court system.
b. Fairness for all licence fee payers, and effectiveness in deterring evasion.
c. Proportionality and ease of enforcement.
1
TV Licensing has contracted most of its day-to-day activities to Capita Business Services Ltd (‘Capita’), which
carries out enquiries in relation to licence fee evasion. Collection of the licence fee, by the sale of licences,
takes place by way of over-the-counter services provided by PayPoint plc (‘PayPoint’) in the UK, and by the
Post Office in the Isle of Man and Channel Islands. Marketing and printing services are contracted to Proximity
London Ltd.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
6
d. The degree to which the regime is easy to understand by all.
e. Where appropriate, practical considerations for effective transition from the current
regime to a different one.
The Review was announced on 9 September 2014 and the public consultation document was published
on 12 February 2015. The consultation period ran from 12 February to 1 May 2015. For the purposes
of the public consultation, the Review Team developed six policy options, which ranged from preserving
the current system, to outright decriminalisation with enforcement taking place through a civil (not
criminal) process. This broad range of options ensured that all possibilities for reform were the subject
of consideration during the course of the Review process.
In addition to the consultation process, the Review gathered evidence
2
through interviews with
representatives of the BBC, consumer groups, Government organisations, individuals involved in the
administration of criminal justice, representatives of the devolved nations and the Crown Dependencies
of Jersey, Guernsey and the Isle of Man, as well as other experts.
Following a detailed assessment of the various policy options, and having regard to the key
considerations set out in the Terms of Reference, the Review has concluded that there should be no
fundamental change in the sanctions regime as it applies to the current licence fee collection
system.
The current regime represents a broadly fair and proportionate response to the problem of licence fee
evasion and provides good value for money (both for licence fee payers and taxpayers). The principal
reason for reaching this conclusion is that within the constraints of the current licence fee collection
system, any change would risk undermining the deterrent effect provided by the criminal offences and
would almost certainly add complexity to the enforcement regime, with a corresponding increase in the
burden of cost.
The Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee has also recently concluded that decriminalisation of
licence fee evasion is not feasible, at least not under the present scheme of licence fee collection.
3
The
mechanism by which the licence fee is collected is a matter that will be the subject of further
consideration in the forthcoming review of the BBC’s Royal Charter.
4
On the basis of the evidence available to the Review, it is concluded that many of the concerns
expressed in relation to the criminal offence provide no compelling basis for change. In broad terms,
2
This Review uses the term ‘evidence’ to describe all the information submitted to the consultation and
gathered by the Review Team, rather than in any technical or forensic sense.
3
‘Future of the BBC’, Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee 2015:
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201415/cmselect/cmcumeds/315/315.pdf.
4
The BBC is governed by a Royal Charter, rather than an Act of Parliament, to underline the BBC's
independence. The Charter and accompanying Framework Agreement are drawn up by the Government and,
together, they set out how the corporation should be run, structured and funded and what its purpose should
be. The current Royal Charter came into full effect on 1 January 2007 and expires on 31 December 2016.
Charter Review is the process by which the Government considers all aspects of the operation of the BBC and
may renew the Charter should it choose to do. At the time of writing this report it is expected that the
Government will soon announce details of the Charter Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
7
the current enforcement regime is operated fairly and efficiently by TV Licensing and the BBC and it
has proved to be successful in reducing levels of evasion.
That said, there is scope to improve the current system in advance of any changes that might follow
the Charter Review, particularly in relation to the transparency of the prosecution process and the tone
of TV Licensing’s written communications. The recommendations contained in the Review are
designed, among other things, to address some of the criticism levelled at the current system of
enforcement and to improve the fairness and effectiveness of the process of investigation and
prosecution.
5
It is also recommended that TV Licensing explore ways to target unlicensed household visits more
effectively.
6
One matter that emerged from the Review process is that in 2012, 70% of those prosecuted for TV
licence evasion were women.
7
On the evidence available it has not been possible to reach any
definitive conclusion to explain the reason for this gender imbalance. There is no evidence of any
discriminatory enforcement practices on the part of TV Licensing. It is recommended that the gender
disparity in TV licence prosecutions should be the subject of investigation and consideration in the
forthcoming Charter Review.
The Review also considers that the investigation and enforcement process would be more efficient if
cable and satellite companies were required to share their subscription information with TV Licensing
and a recommendation is made to this effect.
8
The Review also received a body of evidence to the effect that payment of the licence fee should be
made easier, in order to assist those on low incomes. This could be achieved by amending the
regulations
9
which govern the BBC’s ability to offer flexible payment plans. The Review agrees with
this view and has made a recommendation to this effect.
10
When, as part of Charter Review, consideration is given to the future method of licence fee collection,
it would be helpful to improve public understanding of the activities covered by the licence and how
the licence fee is spent. As a result of developments in technology, the expression “TV Licence” is a
misnomer. Steps should be taken to address the confusion that currently surrounds the licence fee,
both in terms of the activities it covers and the use to which it is put.
11
In addition, consideration should be given to the question of whether non-linear viewing (such as ‘on-
demand’ or ‘catch-up’ broadcasting services) should be included in the licence fee framework, which
it currently is not.
12
5
See recommendation 7.
6
See recommendation 2.
7
The proportion of fines imposed for failure to hold a TV licence in 2012 by gender was 32% male 68% female -
https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-court-statistics-quarterly-july-to-september-2014 (table B4a).
8
See recommendation 5.
9
Communication (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004.
10
See recommendation 4.
11
See recommendation 8.
12
See recommendation 9.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
8
The forthcoming Charter Review is likely to look again at the mechanisms by which the licence fee is
collected. Should there be any change in the method of collection (for example, by way of a household
tax or broadcasting levy, as is the case in Germany), a move to another method of enforcement will
become more practicable and the question of decriminalisation will again fall for consideration.
SUMMARY OF RECOMMENDATIONS
1
While the current licence fee collection system is in operation, the current system of
criminal deterrence and prosecution should be maintained.
2
TV Licensing should explore ways to target unlicensed household visits more
effectively, to increase the likelihood of an enquiry officer making contact with
occupiers.
3
The BBC and the Department for Culture, Media and Sport should explore ways to
investigate and consider the gender disparity in TV licence prosecutions.
4
The Department for Culture, Media and Sport, in conjunction with the BBC, should
explore ways of amending the current regulations to allow simple and flexible payment
plans for those facing difficulty in paying the licence fee.
5
Consideration should be given to the introduction of a requirement for cable and
satellite TV companies to share their subscription information with TV Licensing in
order to improve the investigation and enforcement process.
6
TV Licensing should consider increasing the transparency of its prosecution and
enforcement policy, and provide clearer guidance to those at risk of prosecution. This
guidance could take the form of a code detailing the steps that will be taken before
prosecution, including the public interest considerations that will be applied when
deciding whether to prosecute. Any such code should be published and made
available to suspected evaders at the earliest possible opportunity in the enforcement
process.
7
TV Licensing should consider changing the tone and content of its written
communications with households so as to ensure that they are expressed in
reasonable terms and can be easily understood.
8
When considering the structure of licence fee collection as part of the forthcoming
Charter Review, a move towards a simpler system would assist in improving public
understanding of what the licence fee covers.
9
The Charter Review should look at non-linear viewing as a matter of urgency.
Consideration should be given to the inclusion of non-linear viewing within the licence
fee framework.
Next Steps
This report will be presented to Ministers of the Department for Culture, Media and Sport for their
consideration. The Secretary of State will lay the report before both Houses of Parliament and it will be
presented to the BBC Trust. In accordance with section 77 of the Deregulation Act 2015,
13
the Secretary
of State will set out the response and steps to be taken within three months of the Review being
completed.
13
Deregulation Act 2015.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
9
Chapter 1: Introduction and background
to the Review
Introduction
1. This Review was established to consider whether the sanctions currently in place for failure to
hold a TV licence are appropriate and fair, and whether the regime represents good value for
licence fee payers
14
and taxpayers. Under the current law, by reason of section 363 of the
Communications Act 2003, TV licence fee evasion is a criminal offence triable summarily (in
the Magistrates’ Court) and punishable by a fine of up to £1,000.
15
Background
2. The television licence fee was introduced in June 1946 to cover the costs of operation of the
405-line (monochrome analogue television) service. Prior to this, the licence fee covered only
radio services. In 1968, following the introduction of colour transmissions, a colour television
supplement was added to the licence fee. The function of collecting and enforcing the television
licence fee was carried out by the Home Office until 1991, when these responsibilities were
assumed by the BBC. The investigation into and enforcement of the criminal offence is now
carried out by “TV Licensing”. “TV Licensing” is a trading name of the BBC, and includes some
companies contracted by the BBC to administer the collection of television licence fees and
enforcement of the television licensing system.
16
3. The current licence fee is £145.50, for colour, or £49.00 for black and white. Over 25 million
licences are issued each year,
17
generating revenue in 2013/14 of £3.7 billion.
18
4. A licence is required by anyone in the UK who installs or uses a TV receiver. In this context
“use” means viewing live (or nearly live
19
) television broadcasts on any device and derived from
any source, not solely programmes broadcast by the BBC. The licence fee is paid to the BBC
and the revenue derived from the sale of licences is used largely to fund the BBC’s television,
radio and online services, although it also provides funding for other services such as the Welsh
14
In this report, as in the BBC’s Royal Charter, a reference to a “licence fee payer” is not to be taken literally but
includes, not only a person to whom a TV licence is issued under section 364 of the Communications Act 2003,
but also (so far as is sensible in the context) any other person in the UK who watches, listens to or uses any
BBC service, or may do so or wish to do so in the future.
15
Section 363 is set out in full at Annex D.
16
The BBC is a public authority in respect of its television licensing functions and retains overall responsibility
for these activities.
17
2013/14: 25,419,296 (http://www.tvlicensing.co.uk/about/foi-licences-facts-and-figures-AB18).
18
BBC Annual Report and Accounts 2013/14: http://www.bbc.co.uk/annualreport/2014/home.
19
This includes watching live TV broadcasts on a delay, but does not include ‘on demand’ services:
http://www.tvlicensing.co.uk/check-if-you-need-one/topics/technology--devices-and-online-top8.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
10
broadcaster S4C, the nationwide digital switchover and infrastructure projects such as the
delivery of superfast broadband.
20
The TV licence fee can be paid by way of an annual one-off
payment or by quarterly, monthly, or weekly instalments, and there are various payment
methods available to customers.
21
TV Licensing takes active steps to contact unlicensed
households to ensure that individuals are aware of the obligation to hold a licence and also the
options available for payment.
5. In 2013, there were 178,332 prosecutions for failure to hold a TV licence.
22
This represented
approximately 11.5% of all defendants proceeded against before the Magistrates' Court.
23
While
this is a significant number, it appears that the cases account for only a minute fraction of court
time (0.3% on the figures available).
24
6. These cases resulted in 153,369 convictions, which equates to a conviction rate of 86%.
25
The
most common sentence for the offence is a fine, although some cases are dealt with by way of
a conditional or absolute discharge. Very few people actually appear at court as the vast majority
of defendants make a written plea of guilty, which is permitted by the Magistrates’ Court Act
1980.
26
In some instances cases are withdrawn if the evader purchases a licence.
Motivation for Review
7. A duty was placed on the Secretary of State for Culture, Media and Sport to carry out a review
of the sanctions appropriate for the contravention of section 363 of the Communications Act
2003, by section 77 of the Deregulation Act 2015. One of the issues raised during Parliamentary
debates on the Deregulation Bill was a concern that the criminal nature of the current regime is
not a proportionate response to the problem of licence fee evasion. In particular, it was
suggested that the availability of a criminal prosecution, with a financial penalty on conviction,
and the possibility of imprisonment in default of payment, was not comparable to the sanctions
for non-payment of utility service bills, such as water, gas and electricity.
27
Concerns were also
expressed regarding the fairness of the current enforcement regime as applied to some social
20
BBC Annual Report and Accounts 2013/14: http://www.bbc.co.uk/annualreport/2014/home.
21
Payment options include direct debit, credit and debit cards, cheques and postal orders, cash (via Paypoint)
and TV Licence payment cards. The payment options are prescribed in regulations (Communications
Regulations (TV Licensing) 2004).
22
https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-justice-statistics-quarterly-december-2013 “Outcomes by
offence”.
23
https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-court-statistics-quarterly-july-to-september-2014 shows
1,546,140 Magistrates’ Court cases in 2013. 178,332 of 1,546,140 = 11.5%.
24
Figures provided to the BBC by the Department of Constitutional Affairs in 2005. No more recent figures are
available as this information is not gathered by the Ministry of Justice.
25
“Offences by outcome”, as above. 153,369 of 178,332 = 86%.
26
Magistrates’ Court Act 1980, Section 12(4).
27
However it is to be noted that, unlike these services, TV Licensing is not able to disconnect a non-payer’s
supply or monitor TV usage by way of a pre-payment meter, and so does not have the means with which to
encourage payment before resorting to the court process.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
11
groups, in particular women (who form the majority of defendants in prosecutions for licence
evasion) and those on low incomes.
28
8. The Review’s Terms of Reference also required consideration to be given to the question of
whether improvements could be made to the efficiency of the current system of investigation
and prosecution. It has been suggested in some quarters that savings in time and money could
be achieved by effecting a less radical change than decriminalisation. For example, some have
advocated the adoption of a system similar to the one operated in Scotland, where a fiscal fines
system is operated by the Procurator Fiscal for a range of summary offences including cases
of TV licence evasion.
29
9. Set against these concerns, the BBC has argued that the current enforcement regime is
designed to provide, and does in fact provide, an effective deterrent to evasion and the
existence of the criminal offence has ensured a low rate of evasion at around 5% for the past
five years.
10. The Review has sought to analyse the merits of these competing arguments. This analysis has
been conducted on the basis of the evidence provided to the Review by a number of interest
groups and individuals and in accordance with the key considerations set out in the Review’s
Terms of Reference.
30
11. The House of Commons Culture, Media and Sport Committee has also recently published a
detailed report on the future of the BBC. The Committee’s report includes a valuable discussion
of the future of the licence fee and the issue of decriminalisation. The Committee accepted that
decriminalisation was not a feasible option under the current system of licence fee collection.
Certain observations made by the Committee, relevant to this Review, are addressed in Chapter
4.
Charter Review
12. One highly influential factor behind this Review’s principal recommendation that the sanctions
regime should not be the subject of any significant change is the forthcoming review of the
BBC’s Royal Charter. The close proximity of the Charter Review has obvious implications for
the long-term viability of any changes to the sanctions regime: the Charter Review will involve
an in-depth exploration of the BBC’s operations, and this will involve a review of the BBC’s
funding, including both the mechanism for collecting the licence fee and the process of
enforcement. Any reform of the current regime (such as a move to decriminalisation) carries the
risk of becoming outdated as a result of further reform. If changes are to be made to the BBC’s
funding model, the scheme of enforcement will fall for reconsideration and the case for reform
may become stronger.
28
BBC evidence to the Review. In 2014, 70% of those prosecuted for TV licence fee evasion were women.
29
This fiscal fines system operates as an alternative to prosecution in the sense that, whilst the fiscal fines
system does not alter the criminal nature of the offence, it provides for an out-of-court disposal by way of
financial penalty; this reduces the number of cases coming before the criminal courts. However, the typical
settlement is £75, around half the cost of buying an annual licence. The viability of adopting this option, among
others, has been explored in the course of the Review.
30
The key considerations are set out above at page 4.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
12
Review Methodology
13. The Review Team developed six policy options for the purposes of public consultation. These
options were intended to provide the widest possible scope for potential reform. They ranged
from retaining the criminal offence to outright decriminalisation with the civil courts as opposed
to the criminal courts being used to collect unpaid licence fees.
14. The consultation document was published on 12 February 2015, and by the end of the
consultation period, 1 May 2015, responses had been received from members of the public and
a number of organisations.
31
15. In addition to the consultation process, the Review held a number of meetings with the BBC,
consumer groups, Government organisations, individuals involved in the administration of
criminal justice, representatives from the devolved nations, the Crown Dependencies of Jersey,
Guernsey and the Isle of Man, as well as others including experts in the field of broadcasting.
32
,
33
16. The views expressed by those who participated in the Review represented a broad range of
opinion and the key points to emerge from the evidence are considered in the discussion of the
six options in Chapter 3.
17. It was envisaged at the time of consultation process that the Review would have the benefit of
a behavioural research paper, addressing the impact that decriminalisation would have on the
level of evasion. As things transpired, this proved to be impracticable and, in the absence of its
own behavioural research, a behavioural analysis survey conducted by Harris Interactive
(commissioned by the BBC) was provided to the Review Team. This survey found that the
existence of the criminal offence is in itself a strong factor in deterring evasion. It also found that
the criminal penalties, such as the risk of prosecution or imprisonment, provide the most
effective deterrent to evasion, after a large fine or monetary penalty (in the region of £1000;
significantly higher than the current average fines). The survey further predicted that evasion
rates would rise significantly under a civil model of enforcement. The Review Team conducted
a quality assurance review of the survey and concluded that it was reliable.
34
18. As this Review has been conducted by an independent reviewer, it was not necessary to carry
out an Impact Assessment in advance of the consultation. Notwithstanding the independent
nature of the Review, a limited assessment of the impact of the various options is set out at
31
Details can be found at Annex F.
32
Details can be found at Annex F.
33
It is important to note that this Review took place over the course of the 2015 general election. The roles of a
number of individuals involved in the Review have changed as a result of the election. Most pertinently John
Whittingdale MP was interviewed in his capacity as Chair of the House of Commons Culture, Media and Sport
Select Committee, but is now the Secretary of State for Culture, Media and Sport and will be receiving this
report. There have also been changes to the Ministerial teams of other Departments which provided evidence to
this Review, such as the Ministry of Justice.
34
This quality assurance review is set out in Annex E of this report together with a review of existing literature
on the behavioural impacts of changes in enforcement.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
13
Annex B. It will be the responsibility of the Department for Culture, Media and Sport to consider
the impact of the recommendations contained in this Report, should the Secretary of State
choose to accept any or all of them.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
14
Chapter 2: Current Law and
Enforcement Regime
35
www.tvlicensing.co.uk.
36
http://www.tvlicensing.co.uk/check-if-you-need-one/topics/technology--devices-and-online-top8.
37
Regulation 9(3) of the Communications (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004 provides that “receiving a
television programme service includes a reference to receiving by any means any programme included in that
service, where that programme is received at the same time (or virtually the same time) as it is received by
members of the public by virtue of its being broadcast or distributed as part of that service”.
38
Section 363 of the Communications Act 2003.
39
The Legal Aid, Sentencing and Punishment of Offenders Act 2012 contains a power to increase the
maximum fine level for offences in this band from £1000 to £4000. In the previous Parliament, the Coalition
Government (2010-2015) did not increase the fine level, but this could of course be a matter which a
Government may seek to change.
What is a TV Licence?
A TV licence is a legal permission to install or use television receiving equipment (such as
televisions, computers, laptops, tablets, mobile phones, games consoles, digital boxes and
DVD/VHS recorders) to watch or record television programmes as they are being broadcast. This
applies regardless of which television channels a person receives or how those channels are
received. The licence fee is not a payment for BBC services (or any other television service),
although licence fee revenue is used to fund the BBC along with other services, such as the
delivery of superfast broadband.
35
Who Needs a TV Licence?
Everyone in the UK who installs a television receiver or watches or records a TV programme as it
is broadcast needs to be covered by a TV licence, regardless of the device used to receive the
broadcast.
A single TV licence covers all devices used at a single site, whether home or business (and, for the
most part, portable devices used away from that site).
36
There are different rules for businesses
with multiple premises, or properties such as hotels.
The watching of non-linear broadcasting does not require a TV licence. Non-linear broadcasting is
television programming shown at a different time than when it is broadcast, and includes ‘on
demand’ programming, catch-up television, streaming or downloading programmes after they have
been broadcast on live television, and programmes available online before being broadcast on
television.
37
A person who installs or uses television-receiving equipment without a TV licence is guilty of a
criminal offence under the Communications Act 2003 and is liable to a level 3 fine
38
(currently a
maximum of £1000
39
).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
15
Current Framework
19. The cost of a colour TV licence is £145.50 and the cost of a black and white licence is £49.00.
Concessions are available for blind people, those aged 75 and over, and those living in
qualifying residential care accommodation. The level of the television licence fee, the available
concessions and various payment methods are set out in regulations, principally the
Communication (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004 (as amended).
40
20. The process by which the Government sets the level of the licence fee is known as the licence
fee settlement. The Government consults the BBC over its costs and expenditure, and then
determines the licence amount. The last licence fee settlement was in 2010, at which time the
licence fee was frozen at its current level until 31 March 2017.
21. The licence fee is paid by an individual to TV Licensing, which transfers the sums received into
the Consolidated Fund.
41
The BBC receives its funding in the form of a grant from the
Department for Culture, Media and Sport in an amount equal to the revenue derived from the
TV licence fee, less any administrative costs.
42
22. The BBC uses its grant to fund nine television channels and 57 radio stations; it also provides
a number of other services such as BBC Online and iPlayer. Under the 2010 licence fee
settlement, the BBC assumed a number of additional responsibilities, including an obligation to
provide funding to the BBC World Service and the Welsh public service broadcaster S4C.
43
In
addition, the 2010 settlement provided for an annual payment from licence fee revenue
specifically for the development of superfast broadband. This annual payment of £150m is paid
to Broadband Delivery UK.
44
23. Licence fee collection is managed by the BBC Executive Board,
45
while responsibility for
overseeing the licence fee collection arrangements, and ensuring these are efficient,
appropriate and proportionate, is vested in the BBC Trust.
46
The Trust’s responsibility was first
40
A full list of the amending regulations can be found at Annex D.
41
Section 365 of the Communications Act 2003. The Consolidated Fund is a fund into which all public revenue
is paid and which provides the supply for all public services. The basis of the financial mechanism by which the
Consolidated Fund is operated is governed by the Exchequer and Audit Departments Act 1866 and it is
administered by the Treasury.
42
The BBC receives grant-in-aid from DCMS equal to the revenue from the TV licence fee (less the
Department’s expenses in administering the licensing system - see clause 75 of the BBC Framework
Agreement of 30 June 2006).
43
The detail of how the BBC must carry out these obligations is set out in the BBC Framework Agreement:
http://downloads.bbc.co.uk/bbctrust/assets/files/pdf/about/how_we_govern/agreement_amend_sep11_sum.pdf.
44
Broadband roll-out and use agreement (16 July 2012) between BBC Trust and DCMS -
http://downloads.bbc.co.uk/bbctrust/assets/files/pdf/our_work/local_television/broadband_agreement.pdf.
45
The ‘BBC Executive’ refers to the Executive Board of the BBC, made up of the organisation’s Directors and
responsible for the operational management of the BBC.
46
The ‘BBC Trust’ is the governing body of the BBC. It sets the strategic objectives for the BBC Executive and
monitors its performance.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
16
set out in the 2006 Royal Charter and, under the terms of the Charter, the Trust is required to
ensure that the arrangements for the collection of the licence fee by the BBC Executive are
efficient, appropriate and proportionate.
47
In order to fulfil this function, the Trust committed to
regularly review the BBC Executive’s licence fee collection strategy, as part of the BBC’s annual
report and accounts.
What does the licence fee pay for?
BBC services:
57 radio stations
9 television channels
BBC Online, iPlayer & Red Button
BBC World Service
BBC Monitoring
Non-BBC services:
Funding for S4C
Funding for Broadband and local TV
The BBC Executive must maintain value for
money and secure the finances intended to fund
BBC services for the public at large. The BBC’s
collection strategy needs to be designed to
help people pay for their licence by ensuring
the system is as customer focused as possible.
At the same time it must ensure that it fulfils its
responsibility to the vast majority of
households who pay their licence fee, by
vigorously pursuing those that deliberately
evade payment.
- BBC Trust Review of TV Licence Fee Collection 2009
24. Until June 2013,
48
retailers who sold or rented television receiving devices or equipment were
required to record the name and address of the purchaser or hirer and pass on these details to
TV Licensing. A failure to comply with this requirement was a criminal offence.
49
This information
was used by TV Licensing to target potentially unlicensed usage and was sometimes used as
evidence in criminal prosecutions.
50
Current Enforcement Regime
Investigation
25. The investigation into and enforcement of the TV licence offence is carried out by TV Licensing,
which in turn has a contract with Capita Business Services Ltd (‘Capita’). Capita carries out the
day-to-day operational enforcement activities through its enquiry officers.
47
The BBC Trust has a specific duty under the BBC’s Royal Charter 2006 (Article 24(2)(m)) to ensure that the
arrangements for the collection of the licence fee by the BBC Executive are efficient, appropriate and
proportionate.
48
This requirement was removed by the Enterprise and Regulatory Reform Act 2013, as the Coalition
Government concluded that it “placed an undue administrative burden on retailers.”
49
Section 5 of the Wireless Telegraphy Act 1967 (now repealed).
50
BBC Trust Review of TV Licence Fee Collection 2009: Dealer notifications in 2007/08 resulted in 299,000
licences being sold and 61,000 change of address notifications.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
17
26. Proof of the offence requires evidence that a person has contravened the prohibition in section
363 of the Communications Act 2003, and this is usually obtained during the course of an
investigation conducted by an enquiry officer: either by the officer witnessing the commission of
an offence or by way of an admission made to the officer by an individual.
27. In order to assist its investigations, TV Licensing has compiled a database of unlicensed
addresses. These addresses are the primary target of investigations. Where a TV licence is not
required at a particular address (because no individual within a household has installed or uses
a device to watch live television), the householder may inform TV Licensing of that fact by
submitting a ‘no licence needed’ declaration. This declaration will remove the household from
the list of addresses to be contacted for a period of two years.
51
28. The process of investigation usually involves a number of contacts with an unlicensed
household, initially by letter, followed by a telephone call or visit from an enquiry officer, to
confirm whether or not a licence is required at the particular premises.
29. The primary purpose of household visits is to ensure compliance with the law, and “enable TV
Licensing to remove premises which do not require a TV licence from their enquiries, thus
allowing resources to be concentrated on those [which do]”.
52
30. All household enquiries are undertaken in accordance with TV Licensing’s standards of conduct,
and (in England and Wales) having regard (where relevant) to the Police and Criminal Evidence
Act 1984 and its Codes of Practice.
53
The procedure to be followed by enquiry officers is set out
in Capita’s TV Licensing Visiting Procedures Manual.
54
31. The Visiting Procedures Manual sets out in some detail the procedures for household visits, the
appropriate means of gathering evidence and the appropriate means of communicating with
those in residence. During an enquiry visit, the officers must first establish whether or not they
are speaking to an appropriate person (an adult who normally resides at the address). Officers
are required to introduce themselves and explain the purpose of their visit using an established
identification and verification policy. The Visiting Procedures Manual prescribes a strict process
for the conduct of enquiries, including the information that must be given to or that may be
requested from the ‘customer’. There is also a clear requirement to “treat each visit confidentially
and to make the enquiry without causing offence.”
55
32. The enquiry officer can request permission to enter the premises in order to establish whether
TV receiving equipment is present or in use; they cannot enter unless permission is given and
must leave immediately if this permission is withdrawn.
56
The officer is provided with a standard
51
Although visits may be made to confirm the veracity of the declaration.
52
http://www.tvlicensing.co.uk/about/foi-administering-the-licence-fee-AB20.
53
In other jurisdictions, investigations are carried out in accordance with the requirements of local law.
54
Capita TV Licensing England & Wales Visiting Procedures, 2014.
55
Capita TV Licensing England & Wales Visiting Procedures, 2014.
56
Capita TV Licensing England & Wales Visiting Procedures, 2014.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
18
form which is used to record the details of the visit. This form is retained by the officer (and a
copy provided to the customer) for subsequent enforcement purposes and for possible later use
in court, should it become necessary. At the conclusion of the visit the appropriate person is
invited to sign the form to indicate agreement with any recorded statement of facts. As soon as
there are reasonable grounds for suspecting that the person in question has committed an
offence the officer must administer a caution.
57
33. In certain limited circumstances, a search warrant may be issued by a Magistrates’ Court to
authorise access to a property.
58
Such a warrant is only available where there are reasonable
grounds for believing that an offence has been committed and where TV Licensing is able to
satisfy the court that it has no alternative means to obtain relevant evidence. TV Licensing must
also demonstrate that it has exhausted all reasonable means to gain the cooperation of the
occupant and that access will not otherwise be granted to the relevant premises.
59
A search
warrant authorises a single entry and search of the premises within one month of the warrant
being issued.
34. The search will usually be carried out by two enquiry officers, supported by a police officer.
60
The officers are empowered to examine electronic devices to establish whether or not they are
capable of receiving television broadcasts. Capita’s policy is that a search must cease once
sufficient evidence has been gathered.
61
Prosecution
35. Where evidence is obtained of the commission of an offence, TV Licensing will usually
encourage compliance with the law before embarking on a prosecution. According to the BBC,
its primary concern, at least in the case of first-time offenders, is to ensure compliance with the
obligation to obtain a licence, and prosecution is a matter of last resort. Thus, subject to any
other relevant considerations, where a householder agrees to purchase a licence, it is likely that
no further enforcement action will be undertaken.
62
36. Criminal prosecutions are brought only if the evidence is of sufficient quality to meet the
evidential test set out in the Code for Crown Prosecutors (that is, where the evidence is sufficient
to provide a realistic prospect of conviction). Once the evidential test is satisfied, TV Licensing
applies the public interest test, namely whether it is in the public interest to prosecute. The public
interest test involves weighing factors both for and against prosecution, and taking into account
all relevant circumstances.
57
The caution refers to the officer informing the individual that they do not have to say anything, but it may harm
their defence if they do not mention when questioned something which they later rely on in court and that
anything they do say may be given in evidence.
58
Section 366 of the Communications Act 2003.
59
Section 366 of the Communications Act 2003.
60
The BBC advises that this is not a statutory requirement but is TV Licensing’s preferred policy. On very rare
occasions a search may go ahead without a police officer, if none is available.
61
Capita TV Licensing England & Wales Visiting Procedures, 2014.
62
BBC consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
19
37. As a summary only offence, prosecutions for TV licence payment evasion are brought in the
Magistrates’ Court. TV Licensing acts as the prosecuting authority and is responsible for
presenting the case in court.
38. In 2013, in England and Wales there were 178,322 prosecutions for the evasion offence and
153,369 people were convicted.
63
Of these, 152,664 were fined.
64
It is important to note that the
offence is not punishable by way of imprisonment: the maximum penalty is currently a fine
not exceeding £1,000.
65
Despite the large number of cases, prosecutions take up only 0.3% of
court time. Many defendants plead guilty by post and prosecutions are usually listed at a single
sitting devoted exclusively to hearing such cases. The Magistrates’ Court Sentencing
Guidelines
66
set out common aggravating and mitigating factors and a basis for assessing the
level of any fine. The average level of the fine imposed for licence evasion in England and Wales
is £170.
67
According to figures provided by the Ministry of Justice, 70% of those prosecuted are
female.
39. The TV licence offence is not a “recordable offence” so those found guilty do not receive a
centrally-recorded criminal record.
40. Non-payment of a fine may ultimately result in the court ordering a period of imprisonment in
default of payment, however a period of imprisonment may only be imposed as a measure
of last resort, where there is a wilful refusal or culpable neglect on the part of the
offender
68
, and where all other enforcement methods have been tried or at least
considered.
69
The use of imprisonment in the case of unpaid fines is designed to enforce the
Magistrates’ Courts’ order and is not a punitive measure imposed in respect of the evasion
offence.
41. In 2013, 32 people were imprisoned for non-payment of a fine imposed following conviction for
TV licence evasion.
70
63
https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-justice-statistics-quarterly-december-2013 “Outcomes by
offence”.
64
“Outcomes by offence”, as above. 86% of the cases brought to court result in a conviction. 99.5% of those
convicted are fined and the vast majority of the remainder are dealt with by way of a conditional or absolute
discharge.
65
Section 363 of the Communications Act 2003.
66
When sentencing offences committed after 6 April 2010, every court is under a statutory obligation to follow
any relevant Sentencing Council guidelines unless it would be contrary to the interests of justice to do so. In this
case, the Sentencing Guidelines Council’s Magistrates' Court Sentencing Guidelines (updated October 2014).
67
Ministry of Justice consultation response (2013 figures).
68
Magistrates' Court Act 1980 sections 75 to 91.
69
This is explained in more detail in Annex D.
70
The statistics in relation to those imprisoned for wilful refusal or culpable neglect to pay the fine do not give
any indication whether the defendants in the cases in which imprisonment was ordered were also imprisoned
for other matters or had other outstanding fines. This is addressed in our consideration of Option 1.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
20
Recent Procedural Reforms
42. The Criminal Justice and Courts Act 2015 provides a new single justice procedure
71
which aims
to ensure that the Magistrates’ Court is able to deal more effectively with straightforward,
uncontested cases. This procedure offers an alternative form of proceedings by which cases
will be brought before the court at the earliest opportunity and dealt with on the papers by a
single justice.
72
In other words, the cases are not heard in open court with the result that court
time is saved.
43. The same legislation also introduced a ‘criminal courts charge’, that is a charge levied against
all adult offenders convicted of a criminal offence.
73
The charge levied against persons
convicted of the TV licence fee evasion offence following a plea of guilty is £150.
74
The revenue
is retained by the Ministry of Justice. Those convicted following a trial will be required to pay
£520.
75
The rationale behind the criminal courts charge is that adult offenders should pay
towards the cost of running the criminal justice system. This cost, unlike the fine element of the
penalty, is not subject to means-testing.
76
The criminal courts charge has been included in our
Cost-Benefit Analysis (Annex B), but its potential impact on TV licence fee evasion cases is not
yet clear. It is inevitably the case that the charge will add to the financial burden imposed on
defendants and this is a matter of concern, at least in the case of those on low incomes.
Devolved Administrations and Crown Dependencies
44. There are several differences in the enforcement procedures as they apply across the various
part of the UK and the Crown Dependencies of Jersey, Guernsey and the Isle of Man.
77
45. In Scotland, evasion cases are investigated by TV Licensing, but prosecutions are brought by
the Procurator Fiscal. Under powers provided by statute,
78
the Procurator Fiscal may decide to
use an out-of-court disposal option which means that a defendant may avoid prosecution by
agreeing to pay a fixed sum of money. In Scotland significantly fewer cases are dealt with by
the courts as a majority of defendants utilise this out-of-court disposal option. The advantages
and disadvantages of adopting this approach in England, Wales, Northern Ireland and the
Crown Dependencies (Jersey, Guernsey and the Isle of Man) are discussed further in Chapter
3.
71
Criminal Justice and Courts Act 2015, section 48 (inserting section 16A into the Magistrates’ Court Act 1980)
in force April 2015 http://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/2015/2/contents/enacted.
72
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
73
Criminal Courts and Justice Act 2015, section 54 (inserting sections 21A to 21F into the Prosecution of
Offences Act 1985).
74
The Prosecution of Offences Act 1985 (Criminal Courts Charge) Regulations 2015.
75
The Prosecution of Offences Act 1985 (Criminal Courts Charge) Regulations 2015.
76
The legislation (CJC Act 2015) requires the courts not to take the charge into account when determining other
financial imposition amounts.
77
Section 363 of the Communications Act 2003 applies throughout the United Kingdom and has been extended
to Jersey, Guernsey and the Isle of Man by Orders of Council.
78
Section 302 of the Criminal Procedure (Scotland) Act 1995.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
21
46. In Northern Ireland and the Crown Dependencies there are some slight variations in the
enforcement regime. In Jersey, for example, TV Licensing provides information obtained from
its investigations to the local police authority which then conducts its own investigation; any
prosecutions are taken forward by the Centenier.
79
47. The level of fines imposed in these jurisdictions is broadly comparable to the level in England
and Wales, although the out-of-court disposal in Scotland involves a typical payment of £75.
80
79
The differences in enforcement across the relevant jurisdictions can be found at Annex C.
80
Evidence provided by the Crown Office and Procurator Fiscal Service (COPFS): in 2013/14, 94% of cases of
TV licence fee evasion in Scotland resulted in a payment of £75 (12603 of the 13431).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
22
Chapter 3: Consultation Options
48. Part of the Review process involved identifying and assessing possible options for amending
the current regime of criminal enforcement, including decriminalisation of the TV licence evasion
offence. Six possible options were identified. The assessment process involved considering
whether the adoption of any of the options would represent an improvement on the current
regime.
49. The assessment was carried out by reference to the key considerations as set out in the Terms
of Reference:
a. value for money for licence fee payers and taxpayers in enforcement of the failure to have
a TV licence, including operational, revenue and investment costs of the enforcement
regime to the BBC and to the court system;
b. fairness to all licence fee payers, and effectiveness in deterring evasion;
c. proportionality and ease of enforcement;
d. the degree to which the regime is easy to understand by all; and
e. where appropriate, practical considerations for effective transition from the current regime
to a different one.
50. The Review Team intentionally developed a broad range of policy options to ensure that the
possibility of reform was fully and properly explored in the course of the Review. The six options
are set out below in summary form:
Retain the current criminal enforcement system
Reform of current system: leave the current offence as it stands, but reform the current
criminal enforcement system.
Out-of-court settlement: retain the criminal offence, with an option for disposal by way
of an out-of-court settlement.
Fixed monetary penalty: retain the criminal offence, with an option for disposal by way
of a fixed monetary penalty.
Civil monetary penalty: decriminalise and enforce via a civil infraction.
Civil debt: decriminalise and enforce as a civil debt.
51. Each of these options is analysed in more detail in the sections which follow.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
23
3a. OPTION 1
Retain the current criminal enforcement system
52. Under Option 1 the current criminal offence and existing sentencing powers would be retained
as they are at present. The operation of the current system of criminal enforcement is explained
in Chapter 2 above. In summary, the current system of dealing with TV licence evasion is based
on the existence of a criminal offence, punishable by way of a fine. This is intended to serve the
public interest by providing a powerful deterrent to evasion. The offence is triable only in the
Magistrates’ Court. The conviction rate is 86%. In the vast majority of cases offenders are fined
and the average fine is £170.
81
Overview
53. Taking into account all the evidence available to the Review, and having regard to the key
considerations set out in the Terms of Reference, we have concluded that the current sanctions
regime provides a broadly fair and proportionate response to the problem of licence fee evasion.
The factors that have been most influential in reaching this conclusion are as follows:
i) The need for an effective deterrent in the interest of licence fee payers in particular and
taxpayers in general.
ii) The current high level of compliance with the legal obligation to hold a TV licence.
iii) The relatively low cost of enforcement and prosecution.
iv) The difficulties associated with identifying evasion, and the efficiencies of using the
Magistrates’ Court for the purposes of prosecution and enforcement of the financial penalty.
v) The difficulties that would arise if any of the other options were otherwise to be adopted.
54. We should make clear that this conclusion is based on problems associated with providing an
effective deterrent and efficient system of enforcement under the existing model of licence fee
collection. The case for reform, including possible decriminalisation, will become more powerful
if changes are made to the mechanism by which the licence fee is collected. This will be one of
the matters considered in the forthcoming Charter Review.
55. While we have concluded that the current system of enforcement should be maintained, the
case has been made for improvements in certain aspects of the current enforcement process
and these improvements are addressed in our discussion of Option 2 below.
56. We discuss the factors that have informed our conclusion in relation to Option 1 in the following
paragraphs.
81
Ministry of Justice consultation response (2013 figures).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
24
Deterrence
57. Since 1991 the BBC has had significant success in reducing the evasion rate.
82
In England and
Wales it has been maintained at around 5% since 2005 (levels of evasion are higher in Scotland
and Northern Ireland).
83
The BBC maintains that this is one of the lowest evasion rates in
Europe, and lower than a range of countries comparable to the UK in terms of their public
service broadcasting infrastructure and legal systems. It is certainly lower than Italy (26%),
Ireland (12%) and Poland (65%).
84
58. The existence of the criminal offence is intended to provide a strong deterrent to evasion. The
BBC has argued that a strong deterrent is necessary because it is easy to commit the evasion
offence and investigation can be difficult. In support of its argument, the BBC emphasised that
unlike providers of utility services, such as water, gas and electricity, it cannot meter its supply
of broadcast, switch off its services or control access to its programmes.
59. The arguments advanced by the BBC are supported by a research study undertaken by Harris
Interactive.
85
This research study suggests that the public identifies a large fine (around £1,000),
together with other factors (including the risk of prosecution), as the most effective deterrent
against evasion.
86
The study suggests that evasion rates would increase if the current model is
replaced by either a purely civil or hybrid model (such as out-of-court settlements) involving a
fine or payment of, say, £150. Increases in evasion rates are predicted even if the current model
is replaced with either a purely civil or hybrid model involving larger fines or payments of over
£300.
60. The same study suggests that the existence of a criminal offence is in itself a strong factor in
deterring evasion (with 54% purchasing a licence ‘because it’s the law’ or ‘it’s illegal not to’)
87
and evasion rates would increase significantly under a civil model as they are less effective at
making people pay.
88
61. There is no doubt that the mere existence of the criminal offence plays a significant part in
deterring licence fee evasion, and a move from the current system of criminal enforcement
carries the risk of an increase in the scale of evasion, with a corresponding loss of revenue to
the BBC.
82
BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Enforcement, 2009.
83
BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Enforcement, 2009.
84
http://www.tvlicensing.co.uk/cs/media-centre/news/view.app?id=1362435051910.
85
It is to be borne in mind that the research study was commissioned by the BBC, but was quality assured by
analysts from the Department for Culture, Media and Sport, who agreed that it is a robust study.
86
The study is analysed in more detail at Annex E.
87
Harris Interactive Behavioural Research, BBC consultation response.
88
Harris Interactive Behavioural Research.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
25
Compliance with the legal obligation
62. Since the BBC assumed responsibility for licence fee collection from the Home Office, the
evasion rate has reduced from 12.7% (in 1991) to around 5%
89
(in England and Wales). This is
a notable reduction as even a small increase in evasion has significant cost implications: the
current 5% evasion rate equates to approximately £200m of lost income for the BBC.
90
63. TV Licensing and Capita argue that without the deterrent effect of the criminal sanction and the
powers currently available to investigators, the process of enforcement would become even
more difficult and expensive for licence fee payers.
Cost
64. Under the current system the principal cost to the taxpayer is the cost of court time. The total
number of TV licence evasion prosecutions brought to court in 2013 was 178,332, which
represented 11.5% of all Magistrates’ Court cases in that year.
91
Despite the large number of
cases, they appear to be dealt with efficiently, and take up only 0.3% of court time;
92
with many
defendants pleading guilty by post. TV licence evasion prosecutions are usually listed to be
heard at a single sitting devoted exclusively to hearing such cases.
93
The courts have similar
procedures for hearing traffic offences which are considered to deliver fair and efficient
outcomes.
94
65. The Ministry of Justice has expressed the view that the proportion of Magistrates’ workload
taken up with TV licence prosecutions is “relatively minor” and the extent to which judicial and
administrative resources could be reduced is “limited with minimal scope for cash savings.”
95
It
estimates that the annual cost to the taxpayer of TV Licensing prosecutions is no greater than
£5m a year and, further to this, the government and courts receive the revenue of the fines
(where recovered), which reduces the cost to the taxpayer even further.
66. An estimated £26m of TV Licensing evasion fines are imposed each year,
96
and although the
actual figure collected is lower,
97
court time and enforcement costs are largely met by the
amounts recovered. The Ministry of Justice expects that there will be further savings in court
time as a result of amendments to the system of summary justice effected by the Criminal
89
BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Enforcement, 2009 (the figure has remained at around 5% since 2009).
90
Cost-Benefit Analysis (Annex B).
91
https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-court-statistics-quarterly-july-to-september-2014.
92
Figures provided to the BBC by the Department of Constitutional Affairs in 2005.
93
The Review visited a Magistrates’ Court on two occasions and observed a number of TV licence fee evasion
cases.
94
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
95
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
96
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
97
The Ministry of Justice advises that fines are sometimes revised once means to pay information is provided
and, for a variety of reasons, a number may cancelled or administratively written off for a variety of reasons. In
2012 around a third of fines imposed for TV Licence Fee evasion were collected within 12 months.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
26
Justice and Courts Act 2015, and the introduction of the criminal courts charge is likely to reduce
the burden on the taxpayer even further.
67. So far as costs to the licence fee payer are concerned, the BBC spends around 2.7% of TV
licence fee revenues on investigating and prosecuting licence fee evasion.
98
This figure, which
amounts to £102m,
99
is a significant fall from the 6% spent when the scheme of prosecution
and enforcement was administered by the Home Office.
100
68. During interviews, BBC representatives told us they consider the current system to be both
efficient and fair. We were informed that collection costs were reduced by £9m between 2013
and 2014 and that the contract with Capita is designed to deliver £220m of savings between
2012 and 2020.
101
The Ministry of Justice also expressed the view that the current scheme is
fair and provides good value for money.
Difficulties in investigation
69. The investigation process is undertaken by TV Licensing and Capita on behalf of the BBC. TV
Licensing and Capita informed us that the offence can be difficult to detect and enquiry officers,
with only limited powers of investigation, have to rely to a very great extent on evidence obtained
as a result of their household visits. These visits can sometimes be difficult and are often
contentious. The BBC drew our attention to the fact that proving the offence had become even
more difficult in recent years, because of the expanding range of devices that are capable of
being used as television receivers.
102
Efficiencies arising from the use of the criminal courts
70. Although investigations into evasion can be difficult, the court process is relatively
straightforward and the financial penalties are relatively easy to enforce. As noted, despite the
number of cases, the process of hearing licence fee evasion takes up very little in terms of court
time.
103
In order to facilitate enforcement of the financial penalty, the Magistrates’ Court will
frequently be provided with information by the defendant which enables it to determine whether
an attachment of earnings or benefits order would be an effective method of recovering any
fine.
98
BBC Annual Report and Accounts 2013/14.
http://www.bbc.co.uk/annualreport/2014/executive/finances/licence_fee.html.
99
BBC Annual Report and Accounts 2013/14.
http://www.bbc.co.uk/annualreport/2014/executive/finances/licence_fee.html.
100
House of Commons Culture, Media and Sport Committee, ‘Future of the BBC’, Fourth Report of Session
2014/15, p82.
101
BBC Annual Report and Accounts 2013/14 -
http://www.bbc.co.uk/annualreport/2014/executive/finances/licence_fee.html.
102
BBC consultation response.
103
BBC consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
27
71. Under the current system the BBC has no responsibility for the enforcement of fines, with the
result that the enforcement cost is not passed on to the licence fee payer. The BBC will
frequently recover some of its investigation and prosecution costs by way of an order for costs
against the convicted defendant. In 2012/13 the BBC was awarded £13.1m in costs and
recovered £9.5m, a recovery rate of 73%.
104
Difficulties of reform
72. The two most significant difficulties that pose an obstacle to reform are the increased risk of
evasion and the costs (investment and operational) involved in implementing an alternative
scheme of enforcement. These issues are addressed under Options 3 to 6 below.
Arguments Against Criminal Enforcement
73. Having set out the principal reasons for recommending the continuation of the current sanctions
regime, in this section we consider the arguments advanced against criminal enforcement.
74. The principal argument advanced against the continuing existence of a criminal offence is that
the criminal law is an inappropriate mechanism through which to address the problem of TV
licence evasion. This argument has three principal strands. First, the use of the criminal law is
in itself disproportionate and unfairly stigmatises those who cannot pay the licence fee. Second,
TV licence fee evaders are sent to prison and this is a disproportionate response to the problem
posed by evasion. Third, a disproportionate number of prosecutions are brought against women
and those on low incomes.
The use of the criminal law
75. The argument against the use of the criminal law deserves careful consideration. The criminal
law involves the use by the state of coercive powers and penalties. The mere existence of a
criminal offence requires strong justification, either in terms of the harmful nature of the
prohibited conduct, or in terms of deterring conduct in which the public as a whole has an
interest. Increasingly, at least in England and Wales, the criminal law has been used in the
public interest as a regulatory device, extending to conduct lacking any form of moral turpitude.
76. The TV licence evasion offence is a form of regulatory crime and its existence may be justified
on two broad bases. First, evasion imposes an additional financial burden on the licence fee
payer. For this reason alone it is necessary to mark the importance of compliance with the legal
obligation and deter evasion. Second, the general public has an interest in maintaining the
quality of programmes and other broadcasting services, and the existence of the criminal
offence reflects the significance attached to this important public interest.
104
BBC consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
28
The operation of the offence
77. In its support for the existing sanctions regime, the BBC emphasised that the current
enforcement system was being operated, so far as possible, to reduce the burden on the courts
and to encourage the purchase of TV licences. There are, moreover, restrictions on the
institution of criminal prosecutions and a prosecution will not be brought unless there is a
realistic prospect of conviction and it is in the public interest to prosecute. The offence must
then be proved ‘beyond reasonable doubt’. The BBC maintains that this leads to fewer members
of the public being proceeded against than would be likely under a civil enforcement system
operating where proof on the ‘balance of probability’ is sufficient.
105
This is explored in more
detail under Options 5 and 6.
78. We were informed by TV Licensing and Capita that, as a general rule, TV Licensing will not
initiate criminal proceedings, or will discontinue proceedings already begun, if the individual
subject to investigation or prosecution is a first-time offender and agrees to buy a TV licence.
106
This is true for the vast majority of cases, though this policy is not extended to those first-time
offenders wilfully trying to avoid prosecution (for example, by making a false ‘no licence needed’
declaration, or causing a search warrant to be issued). It is not clear whether this policy is always
understood by defendants and the Review has concluded that the exercise of the discretion not
to prosecute is capable of being made more transparent. This is explored in more detail when
considering Option 2.
Imprisonment not an available penalty
79. During the course of the Review it appeared that some of the criticisms of the current regime
were based on a number of misconceptions. First, there appears to be a widespread, though
erroneous, belief that the offence is punishable by a period of imprisonment. As we have noted,
the maximum penalty is a fine of £1000 and the average fine imposed on convicted defendants
is £170.
80. Given what appears to be a widespread belief that TV licence fee evaders receive sentences
of imprisonment, it is important to emphasise that this is not the case. Imprisonment is available
in certain limited circumstances where a fine is unpaid and where the offender either wilfully
refuses to pay or is guilty of culpable neglect.
81. The sentencing process is explained in the following paragraphs.
105
BBC consultation response.
106
BBC evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
29
Means
82. The sentencing guidelines applicable to Magistrates’ Courts
107
are designed, among other
things, to ensure consistency in sentencing. When determining the level of a fine, the sentencing
court is required to take account of a number of factors (including the seriousness of the offence
and whether it is a first-time offence) and also the financial circumstances of the offender. This
means that the fine should be an affordable sum having regard to the offender’s income and
outgoings. The court has the power to order payment of a fine by instalments; the lowest starting
point for payment of fines is £5 per week, and it is generally recognised that the maximum
weekly payment by a person in receipt of state benefits should rarely exceed this amount.
108
Wilful refusal or culpable neglect
83. Imprisonment for non-payment of fines is only available following a formal inquiry into the
offender’s ability to pay. This inquiry, at which the defendant is present and entitled to legal
representation, often takes place some considerable time after the imposition of the fine and
inevitably after the time for payment has expired. It is conducted by the Magistrates’ Court (not
by TV Licensing), as part of the process of the court enforcing its own orders. It is only where it
is established that the failure to comply with the court order is wilful and culpable, in other words,
where the individual has the means to pay the fine, but deliberately chooses not to do so or
recklessly disregards the court’s order to pay, that he or she may be in jeopardy of being sent
to prison. These matters must be established beyond reasonable doubt.
84. In addition, before imposing a sentence of imprisonment, the court must consider or try all other
methods of enforcement. The other methods of enforcement include applications for deductions
from benefit, attachment of earnings, money payment supervision orders and distress warrants.
It is only where these other methods of enforcement are considered to be inappropriate or futile
that the court is permitted to impose a sentence of imprisonment.
85. It follows that imprisonment is only used as a sanction of last resort, and is not a punitive
measure imposed in respect of the evasion offences.
86. We were also informed that as a matter of practice the Magistrates’ Court will take active steps
to refer individuals in financial difficulties to sources of help such as the Citizen’s Advice Bureau
for advice and assistance in dealing with debt, in an effort to avoid imposing a period of
imprisonment.
107
Sentencing Guidelines Council, Magistrates' Court Sentencing Guidelines (October 2014).
108
Unless on universal credit, in which case we are informed by the Ministry of Justice that deductions may be
higher.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
30
The sentence of imprisonment for failure to pay a fine issued by the Magistrates' Courts is a last
resort and can only be issued if:
1. there has been a means hearing (to establish that/how much the defendant can pay);
2. the default is due to wilful refusal or culpable neglect;
109
and
3. the court has considered or tried all other methods of enforcing payment and concluded that
they are inappropriate or would be unsuccessful.
110
The use of imprisonment
87. A strong theme of the public’s consultation responses was that the use of imprisonment as a
punishment for TV licence fee evasion is disproportionately harsh. As noted above, this criticism
reflects a common misunderstanding.
88. In 2013 there were 32 people
111
committed to prison for wilful and culpable neglect to pay a
court-imposed fine where the fine in question had been imposed for TV licence fee evasion (of
153,369 were found guilty, a rate of 0.02%).
112
It is not possible to say, on the statistics available,
whether these committals to prison were the result solely of a failure to pay a fine imposed for
licence evasion. The Ministry of Justice referred to the possibility that sentences may have been
imposed for non-payment of other outstanding fines that were consolidated with the fine
imposed for TV licence fee evasion,
113
or the offenders may have been sentenced for other
offences.
114
89. Many of those who understood the distinction between the maximum penalty for the offence,
and the availability of imprisonment as the ultimate sanction for wilful and culpable neglect to
pay a court-imposed fine, nevertheless felt that the use of imprisonment in these circumstances
was disproportionate. However, the availability of imprisonment is not an anomaly. Committal
to prison can be used as a sanction of last resort for the enforcement of any Magistrates’ Court
fine, and, as explained above, the use of imprisonment in the case of unpaid fines is designed
109
This is explained in more detail at Annex D.
110
Sentencing Guidelines Council, Magistrates' Court Sentencing Guidelines, October 2014.
111
Justice Statistics Analytical Services - Ministry of Justice. This figure has been drawn from administrative IT
systems which, as with any large scale recording system, are subject to possible errors with data entry and
processing.
112
Published figures relate to all prosecutions brought under Wireless Telegraphy Acts, overwhelmingly S.363
Communications Act 2013 prosecutions -
www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/311319/8-outcomes-by-offence.xls.
113
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
114
This was a view expressed by other contributors to the Review. As a matter of practice, it is not unusual for
offenders receiving custodial sentences for an offence to request that other matters be dealt with as part of that
sentence, including outstanding and defaulted fines. In these circumstances, courts may impose additional days
to a sentence, often to be served concurrently and the offender serves a single sentence. It is certainly possible
that this has occurred in the case of offenders who have defaulted or outstanding fines for TV licence fee
evasion. It is therefore difficult to assess why certain fine defaulters were sent to prison, and the review received
no responses from any individual who had served a custodial sentence arising from failure to pay a fine for
licence evasion.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
31
to enforce the Magistrates’ Court’s order: it is not a punitive measure imposed in respect of the
evasion offence. In this context, it is also relevant to observe that decriminalisation would not
necessarily lead to the removal of imprisonment as a matter of last resort: imprisonment
is available for non-payment of statutory civil debts such as council tax.
115
Not a recordable offence
90. The second misconception is that it is widely believed that a conviction for the offence contrary
to section 363 is a 'recordable offence'. In fact, the offence is not a 'recordable offence', with the
result that it is not included in the record kept on the Police National Computer. While some
stigma inevitably attaches to a criminal conviction, the nature of the offence and the fact that
conviction does not give rise to a criminal record reduces the force of the ‘stigma’ argument.
Disproportionate impact on women and those on low incomes
91. Statistics provided to the Review by the Ministry of Justice show that more women than men
are convicted of TV Licensing offences.
116
This imbalance has been advanced as one of the
key criticisms of the offence by Parliamentarians such as Andrew Bridgen MP.
117
The
exploration for this imbalance and how it might be the subject of further consideration is dealt
with in our analysis of Option 2. For the purposes of considering Option 1, it is relevant to note
that the Review found no basis to conclude that TV Licensing intentionally targets women, or
that its practices are directly or indirectly discriminatory. The cause of the gender imbalance is
difficult to discern, although a number of possible explanations have been advanced. We have
recommended that this matter should be explored by TV Licensing in conjunction with the
Department for Culture, Media and Sport, and a recommendation to this effect is set out
below.
118
92. Concern has also been expressed that the use of imprisonment unfairly affects those who
cannot afford to pay the licence fee. As we have made clear, TV Licensing plays no part in the
process of fine enforcement. Imprisonment is used as a matter of last resort in the cases of
those who wilfully refuse to pay a court imposed fine or are guilty of culpable neglect. There are
nevertheless residual concerns about the impact of the offence on low income households,
particularly as the burden of prosecution on some social groups is likely to increase as a result
of the introduction of the criminal courts charge. These concerns are considered in more detail
under Option 2 where we address TV Licensing’s prosecution policy.
115
Non-payment of council tax is dealt with as a civil debt but a non-payer may still be sent to prison. As with
non-payment of fines, imprisonment is a matter of last resort, after a means inquiry has been concluded and
after it has been proved that the default in payment was either wilful or the result of culpable neglect. The BBC’s
consultation response noted that non-payment of council tax led to 107 people being imprisoned in 2012,
whereas for non-payment of a fine relating to TV licence fee the figure was 51 (and in 2013 had fallen to 32).
116
The proportion of fines imposed for failure to hold a TV licence in 2012 by gender was 32% male 68%
female table B4a of https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-court-statistics-quarterly-july-to-
september-2014.
117
http://www.conservativehome.com/platform/2014/03/from-andrewbridgenmp-2.html.
118
See recommendation 3.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
32
The Scope of the Offence
93. One issue that we wish to highlight in relation to the operation of the criminal offence arises
from the uncertainty surrounding its scope in light of recent developments in technology.
94. It is well-known that a TV licence is required in order to watch live television broadcasts and
that not having a TV licence as required amounts to a criminal offence. There is however some
confusion surrounding the requirement to hold a licence when using an electronic device other
than a television. There have been changes to the licence fee framework over the years which
has contributed to this confusion. For example, a licence was not required in order to watch
satellite transmissions which originated outside the UK until 2003.
119
There have also been
changes and revisions to address technological developments, and this has added to the
complexity of the legal framework.
95. Research conducted by the BBC has demonstrated that many members of the general public
feel that the rules surrounding the requirement to hold a TV licence for the use of computers
and mobile phones are unclear. Around one in three respondents to the BBC Trust’s
consultation claimed that it is not clear when a licence is required, or mentioned
particular areas of confusion in their response.
120
96. One area which seems to be in need of clarification arises from the fact that the current
obligation is focused solely on ‘live’ television, which means television programming which is
received at the same time or virtually the same time as it is broadcast.
121
The importance of this
concept has increased with the growing availability of ‘on demand’ services, whereby electronic
devices can be used to watch programmes at times other than at the time of their first broadcast.
97. The current obligation has created a distinction between linear viewing (traditional television
broadcasting), which must be licensed, and non-linear viewing (such as ‘on demand’ or ‘catch
up’ services), which need not be. The existence of this distinction has created what has become
known as the ‘iPlayer loophole’: those who watch only ‘on demand’ can access broadcasting
services (including BBC services), but are not required to hold a licence.
98. Whether or not the offence should be extended to cover non-linear viewing is a difficult subject
outside the scope of this Review, though it clearly has implications for evasion, and adds to the
complexity of investigation.
119
Communications Act 2003.
120
BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Enforcement, 2009.
121
Regulation 9(3) of the Communications (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004 provides that “receiving a
television programme service includes a reference to receiving by any means any programme included in that
service, where that programme is received at the same time (or virtually the same time) as it is received by
members of the public by virtue of its being broadcast or distributed as part of that service”.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
33
99. What is apparent from our Review is that the term ‘TV licence’ is a misnomer and has added to
the public’s confusion. This term is probably too entrenched in public consciousness to be
changed, at least in the short-term, although a more accurate description might be ‘broadcasting
charge’ or ‘broadcasting levy’.
Conclusion
100. For the reasons set out above, having taken into account the evidence provided to the Review,
and having regard to the key considerations set out in the Terms of Reference, we have
concluded that the current enforcement regime is appropriate and fair and represents value for
money for licence fee payers and taxpayers.
Recommendation 1:
While the current licence fee collection system is in operation, the current system of
criminal deterrence and prosecution should be maintained.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
34
3b: OPTION 2
Reform of current system: leave the current offence as it stands, but reform the
current criminal enforcement system.
101. Option 2 would involve retaining the current criminal offence while at the same time making
improvements to the system of enforcement and prosecution, in order to address some of the
concerns that gave rise to the Review.
Overview
102. On the basis of the evidence available to the Review, and having regard to the key
considerations set out in the Terms of Reference, we have concluded that many of the concerns
expressed in relation to the criminal offence (such as that it leads to the imprisonment of licence
fee evaders), provide no compelling basis for change (at least not under the current model of
licence fee collection). In broad terms, the current enforcement regime is operated fairly and
efficiently by TV Licensing on behalf of the BBC and provides good value for the licence fee
payer and taxpayer.
103. That said, there is scope to improve the current system of enforcement (pending any changes
that might result from the Charter Review), particularly in relation to the transparency of the
prosecution process and the tone of TV Licensing’s written communications. It is also
recommended that TV Licensing explore ways to target visits to unlicenced households more
effectively. The recommendations set out below are designed to address some of the concerns
that have been expressed in relation to the current sanctions regime and to improve the fairness
and effectiveness of the process of investigation and prosecution.
104. One matter that emerged from the Review process is that in 2012, 70% of those prosecuted for
TV licence evasion were women.
122
On the evidence available it has not been possible to reach
a definitive conclusion as to why this imbalance exists, although there is no evidence of any
intentionally discriminatory enforcement practices on the part of TV Licensing. It is
recommended that the gender disparity in TV licence prosecutions should be the subject of
investigation and further consideration in the forthcoming Charter Review.
105. The Review has concluded that the investigation and enforcement process would be more
efficient if cable and satellite companies were required to share their subscription information
with TV Licensing, and a recommendation is made to this effect.
106. The Review received a body of evidence to the effect that payment of the licence fee should
be made easier to assist those on low incomes and that this could be achieved by amending
122
The proportion of fines imposed for failure to hold a TV licence in 2012 by gender was 32% male 68%
female. Table B4a of https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-court-statistics-quarterly-july-to-
september-2014.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
35
the regulations
123
which govern the BBC’s ability to offer flexible payment plans. The Review
agrees with this view and has also made a recommendation to this effect.
124
Discussion
107. The BBC has made major improvements in efficiency since it took over responsibility for licence
fee collection from the Home Office. It has reduced the evasion rate from 12.7% (in 1991) to
around 5%
125
in England and Wales, although levels of evasion are higher in Scotland and
Northern Ireland.
126
This is a notable improvement as even a small change in the level of
evasion has significant cost implications: the current 5% evasion rate equates to approximately
£200m of lost income for the BBC.
127
108. The evasion rate of 5% is lower than most other countries with similar TV licensing systems,
although it is still thought by some to be unacceptable, representing as it does the cost of
evaders using BBC services which have been paid for by licence fee payers. Recovering £200m
of lost revenue could mean maintaining the cost of the licence fee at its current level,
alternatively, it could provide a significant amount of additional funding for the BBC to provide
additional services: either would represent a significant benefit to licence fee payers.
Evasion rates across Europe (2013):
128
Poland - 65%
Italy - 26%
Ireland - 12%
Sweden - 12%
Norway - 9%
United Kingdom - 5%
Austria - 3%
BBC services costing under £200m a year:
129
BBC3 - £109.3m
CBBC - £101m
BBC News channel - £66.2m
BBC ALBA £8m
BBC Radio 1 - £52.8m
BBC Radio 4 - £120.6m
BBC Online - £174.4m
Household visits
109. In the course of its own review in 2009, the BBC Trust noted that over 60% of visits to unlicensed
properties are repeated because the initial visit does not result in contact being made with an
occupant. According to TV Licensing’s data collection, once such contact has been made the
likelihood is that the occupant will purchase a licence within 28 days.
130
The Trust has suggested
123
Communication (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004.
124
See recommendation 4.
125
BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Enforcement, 2009.
126
Evidence provided to DCMS by the BBC, evasion rates 2014: UK 5.4%, England and Wales 5.2%, Scotland
7.3% (taken from BBC consultation response and other BBC evidence).
127
Cost benefit analysis (Annex B).
128
http://www.tvlicensing.co.uk/cs/media-centre/news/view.app?id=1362435051910
129
BBC Annual Report and Accounts, 2013/14.
130
BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Enforcement, 2009.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
36
that by using the existing database to target unlicensed addresses, and by striving to ensure
that contact is made with the occupant, TV Licensing could increase the number of licences
issued at an early stage of the enforcement process, thus avoiding the need to initiate criminal
proceedings.
131
110. More focused targeting of unlicensed households would reduce the number of unnecessary
visits and thus reduce the burden on TV Licensing; it would also benefit those members of the
public who currently receive visits even though they have or do not need a TV licence.
111. Any step that will increase compliance with the obligation to hold a licence and reduce the
number of prosecutions is to be welcomed. We agree with the suggestion made by the BBC
Trust and recommend that TV Licensing should explore ways to target household visits more
effectively.
Recommendation 2:
TV Licensing should explore ways to target unlicensed household visits more
effectively, to increase the likelihood of an enquiry officer making contact with
occupiers.
Efficiencies in licence fee collection
112. As noted above, the costs incurred by the BBC in collecting the licence fee have been reduced
with the result that in 2013/14, for the first time, these costs were less than 3% of licence fee
income.
132
The Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee has noted that this compares
favourably to the peak of 6% collection costs when the enforcement scheme was administered
by the Home Office.
133
The current contract with Capita is structured to deliver savings of £220m
over 8 years.
134
113. The evidence available to the Review suggests that the current court process is efficient, and
will be further streamlined by amendments to the system of summary justice by the Criminal
Justice and Courts Act 2015. The Ministry of Justice informed us that future automation of many
of the (currently manual) administrative processes carried out by the courts will lower the cost
of fine enforcement and increase the amount collected by way of fines.
135
131
BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Enforcement, 2009.
132
BBC Annual Report and Accounts 2013/14.
133
House of Commons Culture, Media and Sport Committee, ‘Future of the BBC’, Fourth Report of Session
2014/15.
134
BBC Annual Report and Accounts 2013/14.
135
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
37
114. Overall, it appears that the current enforcement system provides good value for licence fee
payers and taxpayers and improvements made in recent years by the BBC and Ministry of
Justice have increased its efficiency further.
115. The BBC Trust has made clear its commitment to maintaining value for money and helping
people to pay for TV licences as the following extract from its 2009 review of licence fee
collection makes clear.
BBC Trust review of TV licence fee collection (2009)
“The BBC Executive must maintain value for money and secure the finances intended to
fund BBC services for the public at large. The BBC’s collection strategy needs to be
designed to help people pay for their licence by ensuring the system is as customer focused
as possible. At the same time it must ensure that it fulfils its responsibility to the vast majority
of households who pay their licence fee, by vigorously pursuing those that deliberately
evade payment.”
Gender disparity
116. In its consideration of the current sanctions regime, the Review explored whether there is any
inbuilt bias in the process of investigation and prosecution which unfairly impacts on women or
other groups, such as those on low incomes.
117. Statistics compiled by the Ministry of Justice demonstrate that more women than men are
prosecuted for TV licence offences.
136
The BBC also provided statistics which reveal that of
those interviewed in the course of the enforcement process 67% are female, and of those
prosecuted 70% are female.
137
These figures are stark and clearly indicate that women are
significantly more at risk of prosecution than men.
118. It was suggested by the BBC and Ministry of Justice that one possible explanation for this
gender disparity is that more women than men are present at homes when enquiry officers are
carrying out their investigations during daytime hours. This suggestion prompted the Review
Team to obtain evidence in relation to the visiting practices. This evidence demonstrated that
TV Licensing (in an effort to ensure that officers are not unfairly targeting any particular group
of individuals, either by gender or otherwise) stagger their investigations and visits take place
during both daytime and primetime viewing (evenings and weekends).
138
119. The evidence revealed that the number of women prosecuted is higher than for men across all
visiting hours, and contributors to the Review attributed this to what was characterised as a
136
The proportion of fines imposed for failure to hold a TV licence in 2012 by gender was 32% male 68%
female. Table B4a of https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-court-statistics-quarterly-july-to-
september-2014.
137
BBC evidence to the Review.
138
BBC evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
38
cultural phenomenon, namely that women are more likely than men to deal with household
callers.
139
The significance of this point is that TV Licensing prosecutions must be brought
against an individual evader, rather than a household, and it is likely that the person who first
speaks to the enquiry officer is the person most at risk of prosecution. That said, it has not been
possible to find any definitive reason for the existence of the gender disparity in prosecutions.
Percentage of TV licence fee evasion cases involving females in 2014
140
Visit Time Slot
Interview Under Caution
Prosecution
Non-Prime Time
68%
70%
Prime Time 16:00-18:00
69%
72%
Prime Time 18:00-21:00
66%
71%
Prime Time Weekends
63%
69%
Total
67%
70%
120. While we have found no evidence to suggest that enforcement activity is unfairly and
intentionally targeted at women, or any other group, the disparity in the number of prosecutions
brought against women is striking and further work is required to understand this imbalance.
This issue is linked to TV Licensing’s discretion not to prosecute or to discontinue prosecutions
in the public interest. We make further recommendations in relation to this in the sections that
follow. At this point we simply note the importance of any decision to prosecute and the care
that is to be exercised in ensuring that any prosecution is brought only where it is justified as
being in the public interest.
Recommendation 3:
The BBC and the Department for Culture, Media and Sport should explore ways to
investigate and consider the gender disparity in TV licence prosecutions.
Low Income Groups
121. The BBC provided evidence to suggest that licence fee evasion is not more prevalent in less
well-off households.
141
According to research conducted by TV Licensing, the socio-economic
profiles of unlicensed addresses reflect those of the general population as a whole and not any
139
It may also be the case that more women assume responsibility for household bills such as TV licences, but
we have no basis either to confirm or refute this assumption.
140
BBC evidence to the Review.
141
It was suggested to us by some consultation respondents (John Whittingdale MP, Andrew Bridgen MP,
Christians Against Poverty) that the current enforcement regime has an unfair impact on those on low incomes,
but this was not supported by information we received from the BBC and Ministry of Justice.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
39
particular social group.
142
We were also informed that enforcement activity was not more likely
to take place in areas with a prevalence of lower income households.
122. The BBC also provided information confirming that there is a range of payment options available
to the public, including payments by instalments, designed to assist those on low incomes.
143
The BBC Trust has noted however, that whilst the payment options offer customers an element
of flexibility, the payment plans are more rigid than they would like and have the potential to
create difficulties for those on low incomes. For example, under a cash payment scheme, the
first year’s licence must be paid for within 6 months, and the BBC’s own research suggests that
this is not as helpful as “other annual instalment plans, such as utilities bills, where payment is
spread evenly over 12 months”.
144
123. The various payment schemes were explained in the BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee
Enforcement, 2009:
Payment schemes
145
As an alternative to paying the licence fee up front in one lump sum there are a number of instalment plans to
help spread the cost. The rules surrounding these plans are set and regulated by the Department for Culture,
Media and Sport. The plans enable people to pay six months in advance and six months in arrears. This is
achieved by collecting full payment for the first licence over the first six months and then spreading the cost of
subsequent licences over 12 months.
Whilst the up-front loading of costs also helps protect the BBC from the loss of people who start to pay for their
licence in instalments but stop before the whole amount has been collected, the Trust believes that by making
these schemes as attractive and simple as possible people are less likely to opt out of them.
Under the cash payment plan scheme, weekly or monthly payments can be made by phone, online or at a
PayPoint outlet and are designed to spread the cost of a licence into manageable instalments. The payment
cycle is as follows:
- Year 1, first six months: the customer is issued with a full year’s licence at the start, which is paid for
over six months, so the customer is in arrears for the first six months, at the end of which the Year 1
licence is fully paid for.
- Year 1, second six months: the customer makes half-rate payments and is now saving towards the
Year 2 licence, so is paying in advance. By the end of the second six months, the customer has paid
for half of the Year 2 licence.
- Year 2, first six months: the customer is issued with a full year’s licence at the start, but has paid for
only half of it, so is paying in arrears. The half-rate payments continue and at the end of the six months,
the Year 2 licence is fully paid for.
- Year 2, second six months: the customer starts saving towards the Year 3 licence, continuing with the
half-rate payments, so is paying in advance. By the end of the year, half of the Year 3 licence will have
been paid for, and so on.
Customers who fall behind with payments will get arrears letters and may also get phone calls and texts from
Capita agents acting on behalf of TV Licensing. If payments for arrears are not forthcoming, a customer may
142
BBC evidence to the Review.
143
BBC evidence to the Review.
144
BBC Trust Review of TV Licensing Fee Collection, 2009.
145
BBC Trust Review of TV Licensing Fee Collection, 2009.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
40
be passed to Capita’s debt collection agency, which does not buy the debt but manages it on behalf of TV
Licensing.
Unlike the monthly Direct Debit and Cash Payment Plan the quarterly Direct Debit scheme does not require
any up-front payments. However, in order to join this scheme the licence fee payer is required to pay a £5
annual charge on top of the licence fee because most of the payment for the licence is in arrears.
124. As well as creating a barrier for some would-be licence fee payers, this payment system is
complicated and unnecessarily confusing. However the requirements of the instalment
schemes are contained in regulations
146
over which the BBC and TV Licensing have no control.
The BBC has indicated its willingness to work with Government to explore a simplified approach
with “increased flexibility in the instalment schemes, to allow TV Licensing to adapt payment
plans to suit the individual and help them to stay licensed”.
147
125. This is a desirable objective and the introduction of a simple instalment scheme, tailored to the
needs of individual households, would help those who wish to adhere to the law, but who at
present are unable to take advantage of the pre-payment schemes. This would also ensure that
TV Licensing’s enforcement activities are appropriately focused on those who are intentionally
refusing to comply with their legal obligation and using services paid for by others.
Recommendation 4:
The Department for Culture, Media and Sport, in conjunction with the BBC, should
explore ways of amending the current regulations to allow simple and flexible payment
plans for those facing difficulty in paying the licence fee.
Minority groups
126. The Review has also considered whether the enforcement process unfairly targeted immigrants
and black and minority ethnic groups. An equality analysis
148
carried out by TV Licensing in
November 2011 showed that race does not influence household visit selection; it is the case,
however, that certain areas with a high BME population were found to display many of the
characteristics that influence visit selection. A more recent study, completed in 2014, confirmed
this finding, but noted that areas with a higher BME population tend to have a lower contact rate
(that is the rate of visits where contact is made), with the result that fewer statements are
obtained from householders and fewer cases progressed to prosecution.
149
127. The weight of the evidence available to the Review suggests that there is no targeting of minority
groups and that the BBC and TV Licensing have various strategies in place to monitor diversity
and actively engage with minorities.
146
Communications (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004.
147
BBC consultation response.
148
BBC evidence to the Review.
149
BBC evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
41
128. The BBC provided evidence showing good levels of communication with non-English speakers.
TV Licensing provides information, available online and in leaflet form, in 15 languages other
than English and Welsh.
150
It also provides a phone translation service for use by non-English
speakers which allows customers to set up or pay for a TV licence in more than 180
languages.
151
129. Enquiry officers are equipped with information cards in several languages, and if a customer is
unable to understand English and there is no suitable interpreter available, officers are
instructed not to complete a statement. The Visiting Procedures Manual states that interviews
under caution can take place in other languages and sign language, though interpreters are not
provided by TV Licensing.
152
130. Research conducted by the BBC Trust in 2009 acknowledged difficulties in communicating with
communities which are less likely to be online, and that new arrivals to the UK are not always
aware that the law requires a TV licence for watching live television broadcasts, including their
own national TV programmes via satellite. It has been recommended by the BBC Trust that this
should remain an area of focus for TV Licensing. We endorse this approach and in light of the
Trust’s awareness of the issue, it is not necessary to make any formal recommendation in this
regard.
BBC diversity engagement case studies
“The BBC Executive already has a system of partnerships with stakeholder organisations which
exist to help them reach a wide range of audiences. Its programme for new migrants includes grass-
roots communications activity in local communities, contacting third-party groups who can pass on
information to individuals, such as community groups, employers, local authorities and housing
associations.”
- BBC Trust Review of Licence Fee Collection 2009
“TV Licensing’s extensive social inclusion programme targets hard-to-reach and low income
communities, helping to raise awareness of when a licence is needed, the many ways to pay, and
the consequences of watching TV while being unlicensed. TV Licensing does this by engaging with
national and local organisations which provide trusted advice and support to people in these
communities. A large part of this involves partnering with advice organisations and debt
management charities. In 2013/14 it worked with nearly 70 national and 360 local groups of all
kinds: housing associations; money advice organisations; and minority group organisations.
- BBC consultation response, 2015
150
All visits, correspondence, calls and emails are offered in Welsh if required (Capita TV Licensing England &
Wales Visiting Procedures, 2014).
151
BBC consultation response.
152
Capita TV Licensing England & Wales Visiting Procedures, 2014.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
42
Requirement to purchase a licence
131. One of the factors included in our Terms of Reference concerned the ease with which the
obligation to hold a licence is enforced. In this context one of the issues raised for our
consideration was the inability to compel defendants convicted of the evasion offence to buy a
licence, with the possibility that the evader will remain unlicensed, which raises the possibility
of further offending and the risk of further prosecution. Accordingly, the Review considered
whether it would be feasible to introduce a requirement to buy a licence as part of the current
penalty for the offence, or to permit the BBC to impose charges for periods when the evader
was unlicensed, thus allowing the BBC to recoup the lost revenue (if backdated) or lessen the
loss from evasion (if forward-facing).
132. On analysis, it appears that the difficulties associated with introducing a requirement to buy a
licence as part of the penalty for the offence are twofold. First, the convicted evader may no
longer be subject to the obligation to hold a licence, or may dispute that this is the case, in which
event it would be necessary for the Magistrates’ Court to make a determination on the issue.
Second, it is difficult to envisage how the obligation would be enforced without adding to the
complexity of the enforcement process. For these reasons, we have concluded that to introduce
such a requirement would be impractical and, given the continuing obligation to hold a licence,
would serve no useful purpose.
133. An additional difficulty in relation to backdating is that it would require proof of the period during
which evasion has occurred. In the case of Vehicle Excise Duty evasion, an assumption is
applied and backdating takes place to the expiry of the previous licence.
153
However it would
not be proportionate to apply the same or similar reasoning to TV licences because parts of the
unlicensed period may have been legally unlicensed, or at least arguably so.
134. In summary, it would present a great many evidential difficulties to attempt to establish the exact
period of unlicensed use and to introduce an assumption in relation to unlicensed use would
create a risk of unfairness. The anti-TV licence pressure group TV Licence Resistance
154
argued
that: “any form of automatic assumption about the length of time for which a household was
unlicensed would be intrinsically unfair because: (a) TV might not have been watched during
some or all of the unlicensed period, and (b) the responsibility for the licence may have changed
(possibly informally) during the unlicensed period”.
135. The Review has concluded that any attempt to enable the BBC to recover lost revenue by
charging for the periods when the evader was unlicensed or compelling the evader to purchase
a licence would either be unworkable or unfair, and accordingly the position should remain as it
is.
155
We do, however, emphasise that the priority should always be to encourage compliance
153
Vehicle Excise and Registration Act 1994, section 31.
154
A pressure group which argues for the abolition of the licence fee system.
155
The Magistrates’ Court Sentencing Guidelines make it clear that an aggravating feature of the offence is the
period of unlicensed use and a period in excess of 6 months is likely to result in a higher financial penalty.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
43
with the law and that where an evader agrees to buy a licence, a prosecution may not be
necessary in the public interest. We address this issue in more detail below.
Access to additional data sources
136. Under the current enforcement system, TV Licensing has access to only a limited amount of
information (such as the database of unlicensed addresses) on which to base its investigations.
It has been suggested that providing the BBC with additional sources of information may result
in a more efficient collection of the licence fee, thus reducing the level of evasion.
137. During the course of the Review, the BBC and Ministry of Justice identified a number of sources
of information, access to which might increase TV Licensing’s ability to reduce evasion. One
suggestion was to reinstate the requirement for retailers to notify TV Licensing of the purchase
of electronic devices capable of playing or recording television programmes. The general
consensus of those who contributed to the Review is that this is unlikely to be effective for the
simple reason that many people now watch television on a range of devices (tablets, laptops
and mobile devices) and, as these devices are capable of being used for purposes other than
watching television, it would be ineffective to use sales data as a source of any useful
information. It was also argued that such a requirement would place a disproportionate burden
on retailers.
138. The BBC suggested that access to council tax data or the electoral roll would be helpful in
identifying unoccupied premises and the identities of adult residents of occupied premises.
156
While the BBC accepted that such access would have to be subject to strict data controls, public
responses expressed concern about this proposal and the Review has concluded that it would
not be appropriate to make any recommendations to this effect.
139. Another possibility, raised by the BBC and TV Licensing, was the use of information derived
from pay-TV providers (for example, cable or satellite subscriptions) which could provide a clear
indication of TV usage. It was felt that this would be less intrusive than access to council tax or
electoral roll data, with the potential to be particularly helpful in increasing the effectiveness of
investigations. Having access to this type of data would have the added advantage of making
the investigation process less onerous to householders, in that it would allow more targeted and
possibly less intrusive investigations.
140. It is of interest to note that the Republic of Ireland has recently announced that it may grant An
Post (the Irish Television Licensing authority) access to cable or satellite subscription
information, thus enabling it to check the information against its database of licence fee payers.
The Irish Government has made it clear that access to the information will be available “solely
for statutory functions in relation to licence fee collection and the commercial confidentiality of
the information will have to be safeguarded”.
157
156
BBC consultation response.
157
http://www.irishtimes.com/business/retail-and-services/government-launches-crackdown-on-tv-licence-fee-
evasion-1.1859274.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
44
141. We have concluded that enabling the BBC to have access to pay-TV subscription information
would be a proportionate response to the difficulty of identifying evasion and would have the
additional advantage of making the enforcement process more targeted and possibly less
intrusive.
Recommendation 5:
Consideration should be given to the introduction of a requirement for cable and
satellite TV companies to share their subscription information with TV Licensing in
order to improve the investigation and enforcement process.
Notification that no licence is required
142. The Review considered whether the introduction of a negative notification requirement, as is
currently the case for untaxed vehicles (through a Statutory Off Road Notification, or SORN),
158
would be a practical addition to the enforcement regime. This proposal would aim to increase
the efficiency of enforcement through more targeted investigations.
143. Under the current regime, those households which do not require a licence are encouraged to
inform TV Licensing of this fact (through a ‘no licence needed’ declaration), but there is no legal
obligation to do so. The consensus of those who contributed to the Review was that a
notification obligation would not make any significant improvement to the system of investigation
and the additional regulations and costs involved, particularly the unnecessary burden to
householders, would not be justified. It would also require the introduction of an additional
offence - failure to inform TV Licensing of the fact that a television licence is not needed - which
is undesirable having regard to the likely benefit. For these reasons the review concluded that
it would not be appropriate to introduce any such negative notification requirement.
The prosecution process
144. Under the current prosecution policy operated by TV Licensing, a first-time offender may often
avoid prosecution by buying a licence at any point up to the Magistrates’ Court hearing. Whilst
individuals are informed of this by letter following the enquiry officer’s visit, the policy is not
publicly available and consequently not generally known. When informed of the existence of
this policy, participants in the Review were of the clear opinion that the policy should be more
widely-known. They also argued that this process offered individuals many of the benefits that
would be more formally available through other systems (such as an out-of-court settlement
(Option 3) or a fixed penalty notice scheme (Option 4), without the need for more radical and
potentially costly reform.
158
Vehicle enforcement policy table: https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/vehicle-enforcement-policy.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
45
145. The desirability of publicising the policy was acknowledged by the BBC, and it was suggested
that the public interest test applied by TV Licensing when considering prosecution “already
amounts to a de facto out-of-court settlement system”.
159
The BBC expressed a willingness to
increase the perceived fairness of the current regime, and that one way of doing this was to
make the operation of the public interest test more transparent. In particular, the BBC suggested
that TV Licensing should publish a code which sets out the steps it will take before instigating a
prosecution (including the considerations it will apply in deciding whether it is in the public
interest to prosecute), and to make this available to suspected evaders on the occasion of
household visits, rather than by letter as currently is the case.
146. For its part, TV Licensing had been opposed to this level of transparency and expressed a
concern that it could increase evasion, or at least encourage periods of evasion. Despite this
concern, given that the threat of prosecution remains, and any deliberate attempt to exploit the
policy would be a factor in favour of prosecution, it seems unlikely that evasion will increase.
This is particularly so given that a policy of encouraging compliance rather than resorting to
prosecution is already in operation, and the only difference is that it will be publicised. We are
of the view that the increased transparency could go some way to addressing the concerns
expressed over perceived unfairness in the enforcement process. The stance now adopted by
the BBC indicates support for a change in approach.
147. Set against this, one member of the public argued that an out-of-court system would be
preferable, as he felt that TV Licensing should not have the power to ‘sell justice’ by deciding
either not to prosecute or to discontinue an existing prosecution in circumstances where a TV
licence is purchased by the evader. While we acknowledge the sentiment behind this point of
view, it seems to us that the purchase of a TV licence is a legitimate public interest factor for TV
Licensing to take into account when exercising its prosecutorial discretion. We also consider
that TV Licensing’s principal concern, so far as possible, is to ensure compliance with the law:
if this can be achieved without resort to prosecution, then so much the better for the public, the
individual and the BBC.
148. We also consider that the publication of a prosecution policy will assist in ensuring that all cases
are the subject of careful consideration before a prosecution is instituted.
Recommendation 6:
TV Licensing should consider increasing the transparency of its prosecution and
enforcement policy, and provide clearer guidance to those at risk of prosecution. This
guidance could take the form of a code detailing the steps that will be taken before
prosecution, including the public interest considerations that will be applied when
deciding whether to prosecute. Any such code should be published and made
available to suspected evaders at the earliest possible opportunity in the enforcement
process.
159
BBC consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
46
Tone of TV Licensing communications
149. In response to the consultation a number of individuals expressed dismay at the manner in
which some investigations are conducted and the tone of TV Licensing’s communications. One
contributor to the Review labelled the conduct of enquiry officers “heavy-handed and
threatening”. While this was not the view of the majority of participants, those who did advance
criticisms spoke in terms of “harassment”, particularly in relation to letters received from TV
Licensing, which it was felt were unnecessarily hostile and aggressive.
Case study TV licence appeal (2013-15)
The Review Team examined the findings of a TV licence appeal provided by the BBC Trust.
This contained a complaint arising from “threatening” language in TV Licensing’s
correspondence. The Trust’s response noted that the language had been amended since
receipt of the complaint and it was now more direct and understandable, and included more
explicit instructions about the steps to be taken by customers encountering difficulties in
maintaining payments. However a subsequent letter, sent before the customer’s licence had
expired, contained references to a debt collection agency. The Trust ruled that it was
unacceptable to raise referral to debt collection agencies with a fully-licenced member of the
public, and asked the BBC Executive to make relevant changes to its systems.
160
150. The BBC Trust conducts an annual review to ensure that the enforcement arrangements put in
place by the BBC Executive are “efficient, appropriate and proportionate”.
161
In the course of its
2009 review, The Trust noted that TV Licensing’s dealings with the public should not be
accusatory, and should “aim to be polite, firm and informative”. It was acknowledged, however,
that “this is not always the case” and that the public found them to be “too harsh”. It concluded:
“The BBC Executive must improve the tone of the early stages of TV Licensing’s
correspondence with the public”.
162
It is to be noted that TV Licensing conducted a “major
overhaul” of their correspondence in July 2014, but dissatisfaction with the tone and content of
TV Licensing’s letters remained a consistent theme among some of the responses provided by
members of the public in their consultation responses.
Recommendation 7:
TV Licensing should consider changing the tone and content of its written
communications with households so as to ensure that they are expressed in
reasonable terms and can be easily understood.
160
BBC Trust evidence to the Review.
161
BBC Trust Review of TV Licence Fee Collection, 2009.
162
BBC Trust Review of TV Licence Fee Collection, 2009.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
47
Conclusion
151. This Review has been undertaken within the existing licence fee structure. The principal
recommendation is that the current enforcement system should be maintained, at least while
the current licence fee collection system is in place. That said, there is scope to improve the
current system and address some of the concerns raised in the consultation process,
particularly in relation to the transparency of the prosecution policy. We are confident that these
changes could be implemented while maintaining the deterrent effect of the criminal offence
and without adding unnecessary additional cost to the licence fee payer or taxpayer.
152. We recommend that:
TV Licensing should explore ways to target unlicensed household visits more effectively to
increase the likelihood of an enquiry officer making contact with occupiers.
The BBC and the Department for Culture, Media and Sport should investigate and give further
consideration to the gender disparity in TV licence prosecutions.
The Department for Culture, Media and Sport, in conjunction with the BBC, should explore ways
of amending the current regulations to allow simple and flexible payment plans for those facing
difficulty in paying the licence fee.
Consideration should be given to the introduction of a requirement for cable and satellite TV
companies to share their subscription information with TV Licensing, in order to improve the
investigation and enforcement processes.
TV Licensing should consider increasing the transparency of its prosecution and enforcement
policy and provide clearer guidance to those at risk of prosecution. This guidance could take
the form of a code detailing the steps that will be taken before prosecution, including the public
interest considerations that will be applied when deciding whether to prosecute. Any such code
should be published and made available to suspected evaders at the earliest possible
opportunity in the enforcement process.
TV Licensing should consider changing the tone and content of its written communications with
households, so as to ensure that they are expressed in reasonable terms and can be easily
understood.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
48
3c: Option 3
Out-of-court settlement: retain the criminal offence, with an option for disposal by
way of an out-of-court settlement.
153. Option 3 would retain television licence evasion as a criminal offence while allowing a monetary
penalty to be imposed by way or an out-of-court settlement. This type of out-of-court settlement
scheme is currently used by the Procurator Fiscal in relation to the vast majority of TV licence
evasion cases in Scotland.
163
A similar scheme is operated by the DVLA in respect of certain
vehicle offences.
164
It is envisaged that TV Licensing would offer individuals the opportunity to
accept an out-of-court settlement (payment of a sum of money by way of a penalty) as an
alternative to prosecution. If the offer is not accepted, the case proceeds to prosecution in the
normal way. If the offer is accepted, payment of the total amount is made within a specified
period, usually within 3 to 4 weeks.
Overview
154. At first sight, Option 3 appears to provide an attractive alternative to the current scheme of
prosecution, while falling short of outright decriminalisation. However, on closer consideration,
the adoption of such an out-of-court settlement scheme raises a number of difficulties. First,
there is no equivalent of the Procurator Fiscal in England and Wales and the scheme would
have to be administered by TV Licensing (or possibly by another agency specifically created for
the task). Second, if the scheme were to be administered by TV Licensing, it would be for TV
Licensing to set the figure of the out-of-court settlement (unless it were prescribed by statute or
contained in regulations), and it would be for TV Licensing to decide on the cases in which it
was appropriate to make the offer of settlement. Third, whether or not the scheme is
administered by TV Licensing, the creation of such a scheme would require the investment of
resources and training which is likely to be costly. Fourth, setting the figure of the out-of-court
settlement amount is likely to be difficult and controversial. Fifth, the implementation of such a
scheme carries the risk of increased evasion, although the extent of the risk is likely to depend
on the amount fixed as the settlement figure. Sixth, an out-of-court settlement scheme may
impact unfairly on defendants who cannot afford to pay the full amount of the penalty within 28
days. Finally, even if such a scheme were to be implemented, it might soon become overtaken
by events following the forthcoming Charter Review. It is for these reasons that the Review
made no recommendation in relation to Option 3.
155. In the following paragraphs we consider the merits of Option 3 based on the evidence provided
to the Review and having regard to the key considerations as set out in the Terms of Reference.
163
Section 302 of the Criminal Procedure (Scotland) Act 1995. The Procurator Fiscal has the power to offer.
Fiscal fines for almost all offences which could otherwise be tried summarily.
164
https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/vehicle-enforcement-policy.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
49
Discussion
156. On its face, this option would seem to provide greater value for money for the taxpayer, as there
would be fewer cases proceeding to the Magistrates’ Court for prosecution. The out-of-court
settlement would allow individuals an additional opportunity to avoid the court process by paying
an agreed amount to the BBC. In Scotland, the vast majority of TV Licensing cases are dealt
with in this way, with a consequential saving in court time and resources. The Voice of the
Listener and Viewer
165
supported the adoption of an out-of-court settlement scheme: We
believe it would be preferable if licence fee evasion cases were disposed of via an out-of-court
fine, avoiding the necessity of a court hearing. This would mean significantly fewer cases would
be dealt with through the courts, which would reduce costs both for offenders and the courts. It
would also reduce the inconvenience for individuals caused by loss of income or travel costs
attending court.”
166
Andrew Bridgen MP commented that the out-of-court settlement system
appeared to be a more efficient system than the one currently in place.
167
157. The Ministry of Justice agreed that there could be a cost saving by using a system of out-of-
court settlement, but argued that the saving would be limited (on the basis that the existing
system is efficient and does not impose a significant burden to the taxpayer in terms of cost).
Significantly, the Ministry of Justice believes the cost saving would only accrue if evasion
remained at the current level, while anything more than a minimal increase in the rates of
evasion would offset the savings in costs.
168
Additionally the Ministry of Justice noted that the
court would no longer receive fine revenue and whether or not it would result in a saving to the
taxpayer would depend on a number of factors (the acceptance rate, enforcement costs and
level of the penalty). These factors are considered below.
158. In addition to the potential benefit to the taxpayer, Option 3 also has the potential to provide
good value for licence fee payers. TV Licensing would no longer be taking on the role of
prosecuting a large number of cases through the Magistrates’ Court; prosecutions would only
take place in those cases where the out-of-court settlement had been rejected or those in which
it was inappropriate to proceed by way of such a settlement.
159. An idea of the possible scale of the cost saving can be gleaned from the operation of the out-
of-court settlement system in Scotland, where TV Licensing passes its cases to the Procurator
Fiscal and where, from that point onwards, any prosecution costs are incurred by the Crown
Office. In 2014, the costs of prosecution incurred by TV Licensing were 38% lower per case in
Scotland than in England and Wales.
169
It is the case, however, that the taxpayer bears the
burden of funding the Procurator Fiscal.
165
A consumer group representing listeners and viewers on a range of broadcasting issues.
166
Voice of the Listener and Viewer consultation response. The number of cases brought to the Magistrates
Court in 2013/14 was 178,332, this represents an estimated 0.3% of court time.
167
Andrew Bridgen MP evidence to the Review.
168
Ministry of Justice evidence session.
169
In 2014 the cost to TV Licensing of prosecution in Scotland was £74.90 compared to £120.81 for England
and Wales. BBC evidence provided to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
50
160. Despite the superficial value of comparisons with the scheme operated by the Procurator Fiscal,
the Scottish example needs to be approached with a degree of caution as there is no equivalent
of the Procurator Fiscal in England and Wales. It follows that an out-of-court settlement scheme
in England and Wales would have to be administered by TV Licensing (or possibly another
agency) with the result that the cost of enforcement would be borne by the licence fee payer (or
possibly the taxpayer).
170
A number of consultation respondents expressed the view that TV
Licensing should not be given the power to administer the out-of-court settlement, nor should
TV Licensing be able to set the level of the payment.
171
Others focused on the fact that such a
scheme would require the BBC to take on a very different role and possibly impact on how it is
perceived as an organisation by the public. The BBC Executive stated that to administer an out-
of-court settlement system would present a number of difficulties as TV Licensing does not have
the expertise to set and enforce fiscal fines. For these reasons, the BBC Executive suggested
that it would be more appropriate for any such scheme to be administered by an independent
adjudicator.
172
However the creation of a new administrative body would involve additional costs
in each of the separate jurisdictions.
161. Quite apart from the potential cost arising from the implementation of such a scheme, there are
other potential difficulties. These arise principally from trying to estimate the number of evaders
likely to agree to the out-of-court settlement, the potential problems involved in recovery of the
penalty, and the problems involved in setting the amount of the out-of-court penalty.
Number of evaders diverted
162. As the Ministry of Justice recognized, the taxpayer would only benefit from the adoption of a
scheme of out-of-court settlements if a large number of cases were diverted from the
Magistrates’ Court. However, if fewer evaders than expected accepted the offer of the
settlement, or the evasion level increased, which in turn led to more cases being investigated
and prosecuted, this would have a negative impact on the value of such a scheme to the
taxpayer. Several public consultation responses raised these or similar concerns.
Recovery of the penalty
163. An additional difficulty is the uncertainty of whether a move to an out-of-court settlement scheme
would result in the successful collection of penalty monies. As is currently the case with court-
imposed fines, defaults in payment are likely to occur. In the event of default, there would be a
reduction in the revenue available to the taxpayer and a cost burden arising from the process
of enforcement.
173
The revenue derived from the DVLA out-of-court settlement scheme appears
170
This would also be the position in other jurisdictions, whether or not administered by TV Licensing.
171
Andrew Bridgen MP and John Whittingdale MP evidence to the Review.
172
BBC Executive evidence to the Review.
173
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
51
to be significantly less than that received from prosecutions and the compliance rate with court
fines appears to be higher.
174
Level of penalty
164. A crucial element, in terms of feasibility, is the level of the financial penalty imposed by way of
settlement. The significance of this point is that the level of the settlement will have a direct
bearing on the incentive to obtain and pay for a licence rather than evade.
165. The Ministry of Justice argued that the settlement would need to be set at a level high enough
to deter evasion (that is, higher than the cost of a TV licence) and cover the running costs of
the scheme, but low enough to encourage individuals to take up the offer.
175
The problem is that
if the penalty is set too high, the evader would see the courts as the preferred option as it may
be possible to receive a lower means-tested penalty. On the other hand if the penalty is set too
low any increase in evasion would have a significant impact on revenue;
176
this would
significantly reduce any benefit that might otherwise accrue to the licence fee payer. As the
average fine under the current system is £170
177
the settlement figure would need to be lower
than this amount but higher than the current level of the colour licence fee at £145.50.
178
166. The level of the financial penalty is £75 in Scotland and, as the BBC has pointed out, evasion
levels in Scotland are higher than in England and Wales.
179
174
Evidence provided by the Ministry of Justice (in reference to an earlier Home Office review).
175
This was also the view of the Home Office in an earlier review.
176
BBC evidence submitted to the Review. Each 1% rise in evasion rate would amount to £39m in lost revenue
for the BBC.
177
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
178
The Ministry of Justice suggested that there was potential for orchestrated campaigns to evade the fee if the
out-of-court settlement were to cost less than buying a licence, as individuals may choose to run the risk of
being caught and then pay the out-of-court settlement rather than paying for the higher cost of a licence.
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
179
The evasion rates in Scotland (7.3%) is significantly higher than in England (5.2%). The BBC attributes this,
at least in part, to the out-of-court settlement scheme. The Criminal Proceedings etc. (Reform) (Scotland) Act
2007 amended the Criminal Procedure (Scotland) Act 1995 so that an offer of fiscal fine was deemed accepted
if the alleged offender failed to provide notice of refusal within 28 days of the offer. This change in legislation led
to an increase in the number of cases that received a fiscal fine. Prior to this an offer of fiscal fine that was not
accepted required the Procurator Fiscal to review the case for prosecution or other measures. And prior to 2007
evasion rates in Scotland were lower than their current rate, at 5.9%. However this was still around 1% higher
than in England and Wales. Despite evidence that since 2007 evasion has increased at a higher rate in
Scotland, with a notable increase of 2% between 2010 and 2011, this Review has not seen any evidence to
suggest that this is necessarily causally related to the use of the out-of-court settlement system. Although the
research conducted by Harris Interactive would support such a view, there are possible alternative explanations
for the difference: for example, the perception of the BBC in Scotland, socioeconomic factors, or technical
factors such as improvements in the measurement of evasion in 2010. It is the case, however, none of these
explanations is supported by evidence sufficient to enable clear conclusions to be drawn. If this option were to
be considered, more research into the impact of the out-of-court settlement system in Scotland would be
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
52
Deterrence
167. Although the out-of-court settlement system retains the possibility of a criminal prosecution, the
BBC Trust felt that any move away from the scheme of enforcement as it currently operates
would create a perception that the offence was now considered to be ‘less serious’ than was
previously the case and this might lead to an increase in evasion.
180
168. Harris Interactive conducted a piece of behavioural research which explored whether a scheme
similar to the out-of-court settlement scheme in Option 3
181
would have an impact on evasion.
This research predicted that under such a scheme, evasion would rise from the current rate of
5% to 6%. Such an increase would represent £39m in revenue lost to the BBC.
Low income groups
169. A number of consultation respondents saw Option 3 as having the potential to operate unfairly
in respect of those on low incomes. It was felt that an out-of-court settlement penalty was
disproportionately weighted against those in financial difficulty as they would be more likely to
decline the offer of a settlement amount that had to be paid in a single sum and would instead
elect to proceed to the Magistrates' Court.
170. Means-testing would be a possible way of addressing this problem, but this would add a further
layer of complexity and increase the costs of administering the scheme. On the other hand, not
to means-test is likely to have an effect on the rate of acceptance; individuals not able to pay
the settlement amount in a single one-off payment will elect to face a prosecution. It may, of
course, be possible to introduce a scheme of instalment payments (as exists under the current
scheme for court-imposed fines), but this too would add yet another layer of complexity and
increase the cost of administering the scheme.
182
A review by the Home Office concluded that
an out-of-court settlement regime offering a range of payment schemes could not be operated
efficiently.
183
helpful. Sources - BBC evidence to the Review; ‘TV licence evasion in Scotland’, May 2015; BBC Trust review
of TV licence collection, 2009. This is also discussed in Annex B.
180
BBC Trust evidence to the Review.
181
The Harris Interactive research paper on behavioural changes did not explore specifically an out-of-court
settlement, but the ‘hybrid’ model is similar enough that we can use it as a proxy. In the Harris hybrid model,
first-time offenders receive a monetary penalty while multiple offenders are prosecuted through the criminal
courts. This bears a similarity to an out-of-court settlement scheme, wherein offenders who refuse or are not
offered an out-of-court settlement would be prosecuted through the Magistrates’ Court as under the current
process.
182
The out-of-court settlement system in Scotland does allow for payment of the settlement amount to be made
by instalments, however, these must be made within 28 days (Crown Office and Procurator Fiscal Service
evidence to Review). The DVLA scheme does not offer any flexibility in payment as, in the event of default, this
would create potential difficulties in enforcement.
183
Ministry of Justice evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
53
171. The Voice of the Listener and Viewer argued that the inability to make payments by way of
instalments was a significant disadvantage as “it might make the payment of fines less
sustainable for those who are less well off.”
184
172. Christians Against Poverty
185
felt that while overall an out-of-court settlement scheme
represented an improvement on the current regime involving the payment of court fines in
England and Wales, it had the disadvantage that “a person’s means are not assessed with an
out-of-court settlement, so those on low income would be particularly impacted by this
system.
186
Christians Against Poverty also felt this option was weighted unfairly against some
vulnerable people, and noted that “If a person...fails to understand how to react to the
demands, they will still end up in the Magistrates Court. Therefore, this system is
still...complex and disproportionate.”
187
It was also suggested that a maximum 28 days in which
to make payment did not provide sufficient flexibility for those on low incomes, who would be
forced to default to the Magistrates' Court system where they might receive a lower, means-
tested fine.
Burden of proof
173. An additional point raised in the course of the Review is fairness to those who are accused of
evasion. Christians Against Poverty argued that ‘there may be lower evidence requirements
for out-of-court penalties to be issued, meaning that more mistakes will be made,
adversely impacting those who have not evaded.
188
However, as any out-of-court settlement
scheme would operate using the evidential and public interest test, as in the current system,
this concern, while well-motivated, does not appear to raise any significant practical difficulty.
Practical considerations: Crown Dependencies
174. There are a number of considerations to be taken into account concerning the practical
applicability of the out-of-court settlement system to the Crown Dependencies of Jersey and
Guernsey. Whilst there is no equivalent to the Procurator Fiscal in England and Wales, there is
a process similar to the out-of-court settlement in operation in Jersey. The out-of-court
settlement closely resembles the Parish Hall inquiry where there is a power vested in the
Centenier
189
to levy a fine summarily. Whilst the power to levy a fiscal fine is not currently
available for TV Licensing offences, it would be possible to achieve this through an Order in
Council and to do so would be “entirely consistent with existing Jersey legal structures and the
jurisdiction of the Centeniers.
190
184
Voice of the Listener and Viewer consultation response.
185
A debt counselling charity.
186
Christians Against Poverty consultation response.
187
Christians Against Poverty consultation response.
188
Christians Against Poverty consultation response.
189
A Centenier is a senior member of the Honorary Police of Jersey. In addition to general policing matters, the
Centenier in Jersey remains the only officer entitled to charge and bail offenders. The Centenier presides at
Parish Hall Enquiries and acts as prosecuting officer before the Magistrates’ Court.
190
Government of Jersey consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
54
175. There are no legal barriers to implementing such a scheme in the Bailiwick of Guernsey,
however the Government of Guernsey felt that the decision on whether to permit an out-of-court
settlement in any case, and any discretion as to the quantum of penalty, would have to be
exercised locally rather than by TV Licensing or UK officials.
Current prosecution policy
176. The BBC argued that as, under the current system of enforcement, prosecutions for first-time
offenders are often discontinued, an out-of-court settlement system might actually remove an
opportunity for individuals to avoid a monetary penalty. The Ministry of Justice also made the
point that TV Licensing already discontinues a number of prosecutions where the evader
purchases a licence.
“TV Licensing currently has the ability to accept the purchase of a TV licence whenever it
identifies a person who has evaded paying the TV licence fee. It is the experience of the
Magistrates' Courts that it is rare for the [sic] TV Licensing to proceed with a prosecution
where a TV licence is subsequently purchased.
191
The majority of the 13% of prosecutions
that are not found guilty will be where a TV Licence is purchased after proceedings have been
initiated.”
- Ministry of Justice consultation response
177. It is the case, however, as we have noted above,
192
that these opportunities are neither widely
publicised nor generally known.
Key considerations
178. When judged against the key considerations set out in the Terms of Reference the weight of
the evidence available to the Review suggests that the introduction of the out-of-court
settlement scheme would involve significant investment and operational costs which would fall
to the taxpayer and the licence fee payer. It also carries the risk of an increase in licence evasion
with a corresponding loss of revenue. While such a scheme could provide a proportionate
response to the problem of licence evasion simply in terms of penalty, there are practical
difficulties arising from the implementation and operation of such a scheme, and these
difficulties would outweigh any potential advantages.
Conclusion
179. In Scotland the out-of-court settlement system administered by the Procurator Fiscal is available
for a range of offences. A number of consultation respondents were in favour of Option 3 as
they felt it would offer better value for money for the taxpayer and provide an additional
191
This policy generally applies only to first-time offenders.
192
See discussion of Options 1 and 2.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
55
opportunity for individuals to avoid prosecution.
193
Despite these arguments, the evidence we
have examined makes clear that the current system already offers a number of opportunities
for evaders to avoid prosecution and it has been made clear that the primary concern of TV
Licensing is not to prosecute, but to encourage compliance with the law. Putting an out-of-court
settlement system in place would, to a certain extent, formalise existing arrangements, but with
significant practical ramifications. The principal risk is that it will add complexity to the
enforcement regime and impose a significant cost burden on the licence fee payer and taxpayer.
There is also a possibility that the introduction of an out-of-court settlement scheme would not
significantly reduce the burden on the courts; evaders may choose not to pay the penalty, in
which case a prosecution would follow. It is also the case that an out-of-court settlement scheme
is less likely to be attractive to those on low incomes. Accordingly, we have concluded that
Option 3 would not provide a viable mechanism for the efficient and fair disposal of TV licence
evasion cases.
193
For example the Voice of the Listener and Viewer consultation response and Andrew Bridgen MP evidence
to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
56
3d. OPTION 4
Fixed monetary penalty: retain the criminal offence, with an option for disposal by
way of a fixed monetary penalty.
180. Option 4 would retain TV licence evasion as a criminal offence, while allowing a fixed monetary
penalty to be imposed as a formal alternative to prosecution. This option is similar to Option 3
in that the rationale for each is that they are intended to provide a swift and effective out-of-
court disposal, thus reducing the burden on the courts. However, unlike Option 3, Option 4
involves the possibility of an out-of-court disposal by way of a fixed monetary penalty in every
case of evasion. Under Option 4, a penalty notice (or a notice of an intention to impose a fixed
penalty) would be issued by the authorised enforcement agency (TV Licensing) at the point at
which an offence is committed, for example, at the time a TV Licensing enquiry officer witnesses
an offence on the occasion of a household visit. In the event of default of payment the fixed
penalty notice would be enforced without resort to prosecution or, as an alternative, the case
would proceed to the Magistrates’ Court in the usual way.
194
181. There are a number of offences for which fixed penalty notices are available and a sample of
the offences together with the amount of the fixed penalty appear in the following table:
Offence
Offence creating provision
Amount
Disorderly behaviour
Public Order Act 1986, section 5
£80
Drunk and disorderly
Criminal Justice Act 1967, section 91
£80
Sale of alcohol to drunk person on
relevant premises (not including
off-licences)
Licensing Act 2003, section 141
£80
Sale of alcohol to persons under
18 (staff only, licensees should be
subject to a summons)
Licensing Act 2003, section 146
£80
Brakes, steering or tyres defect
Road Traffic Act 1988, section 41A
£60
Driving other than in accordance
with licence
Road Traffic Act 1988, section 87(1)
£60
Failing to comply with traffic sign
Road Traffic Act 1988, section 36
£60
Failing to supply details of driver’s
Road Traffic Act 1988, section 172
£120
194
Under a number of existing fixed penalty notice schemes if the penalty is not paid then, after a specified
time, a fine is registered in an amount in excess of the original fixed penalty. In other schemes the fixed penalty
is subject to a right to dispute guilt in court.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
57
identity
No test certificate
Road Traffic Act 1988, section 47
£30
Pelican/ zebra crossing
contravention
Road Traffic Regulation Act 1984, section
25(5)
£60
Railway fare evasion (where
penalty notice scheme in
operation by train operator)
Railways (Penalty Fares) Regulations 1994
£20 or twice
the full single
fare to next
stop,
whichever is
greater
Seat belt offences
Road Traffic Act 1988, section 14
£30
Speeding
Road Traffic Regulation Act 1984, section
89(1)
£60
182. In recent years the use of fixed monetary penalties has become increasingly common and the
Regulatory Enforcement and Sanctions Act 2008 provides that a Minister of the Crown may by
order confer on a regulator (as defined in the Act) the power by notice to impose a fixed
monetary penalty on a person in relation to a relevant offence (also defined in the Act).
195
The
Act also provides that the power may only be conferred in relation to a case where the offence
is capable of being proved beyond reasonable doubt.
196
183. According to Ministry of Justice guidance, the aim of a penalty notice is to offer a “quick and
effective alternative disposal option for dealing with low-level… offending. To deliver a swift and
simple method of deterrence… to reduce the amount of time…attending court, while
simultaneously reducing the burden on the courts.”
197
Overview
184. As in the case of Option 3, Option 4 appears at first sight an attractive alternative to the current
system of criminal prosecution. There are, however, a number of potential problems. First, there
is the issue of an increased risk of evasion. The proportion of individuals who elect to pay the
penalty amount in full and thus avoid prosecution is crucial to the success of a fixed penalty
scheme. If the proportion is high this can lead to a saving in court time and costs; if the proportion
is low the process will simply add an additional layer of complexity and bureaucracy to the
process of enforcement and operational costs may increase. This means that the amount of the
penalty would have to be fixed at a level so as to encourage acceptance while at the same time
providing a disincentive to evasion. As is the case with Option 3, this would suggest a figure
195
Regulatory Enforcement and Sanctions Act 2008, section 36.
196
Regulatory Enforcement and Sanctions Act 2008, section 39.
197
Ministry of Justice Penalty Notice for Disorder Guidance, 2014, p1.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
58
somewhere between the current cost of a colour licence (£145.50) and the average level of fine
(£170). Such a figure may not provide an attractive alternative option when the amount has to
be paid in full within a limited period, but setting a figure lower than £145.50 runs the risk of
increasing evasion with a corresponding loss of revenue.
185. There is also the problem of administrative complexity. Under the scheme provided by the
Regulatory Enforcement and Sanctions Act 2008, the regulator/prosecutor must first serve a
notice of an intention to impose a fixed penalty. This notice of intent offers the individual an
opportunity to discharge liability for the fixed monetary penalty by payment of a prescribed sum
(which must be less than or equal to the amount of the penalty). If the individual does not
discharge his or her liability, he or she may make representations in relation to the proposed
imposition of the fixed monetary penalty. The regulator must, at the end of the period for making
representations and objections, decide whether to impose the penalty. Where the regulator
decides to impose such a penalty, the individual on whom it is imposed may appeal against the
decision to impose it. The appeal lies either to the First-Tier Tribunal or another tribunal created
under an enactment. Where the fixed monetary penalty is not discharged, it remains possible
for criminal proceedings to be instituted for the offence.
198
186. As is apparent, the creation of a scheme for fixed monetary penalties for TV licence fee evasion
may involve significant investment cost (at least in the short term) with no guarantee that it
would be effective or reduce to any significant extent the involvement of the courts. There will
also be costs involved in the process of enforcement. Another significant objection to the fixed
monetary penalty scheme is that it would take time to implement, by which time the basis of
licence fee collection may have changed as a result of the forthcoming Charter Review. For
these reasons, the Review does not recommend the implementation of Option 4.
187. In the paragraphs that follow we discuss the merits or otherwise of implementing Option 4
having regard to the evidence available to the Review and the key considerations contained in
the Terms of Reference.
Value for money
188. Under Option 4, value for money to the taxpayer lies in the fact that cases would be diverted
from the Magistrates’ Court, thus reducing the burden on the criminal justice system. The fixed
monetary penalty notice (or a notice of intention to issue a fixed monetary penalty notice) would
be issued at the time of the commission of the offence and, if the penalty is accepted, no further
investigation or prosecution would be necessary. Those wishing to contest liability would be
entitled to challenge the notice or decline to pay the amount, in which case the question of
liability would have to be determined, either by adjudication or prosecution. Andrew Bridgen MP
198
In some fixed penalty notice schemes if the penalty is not paid then, after a specified time, a fine is
registered at an amount significantly in excess of the original penalty and enforcement of the amount due can
then take place.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
59
expressed the view that this system would be more efficient than the current system of
enforcement.
199
189. The introduction of a fixed penalty notice scheme for TV licence evasion is likely to be costly for
the BBC as it would need to invest in the scheme and administer its operation. This would add
to the financial burden on the licence fee payer. It is possible that the long-term savings would
eventually cover the costs of the system, but this is dependent on the success of the scheme.
It also depends on the current licence fee collection model remaining in place over the long
term.
190. The BBC has stated that it would expect its collection costs to be higher using this model than
under the current system and noted that it is not clear that enforcement costs would be
recoverable through the fixed penalty process.
200
191. As in the case of Option 3, the Ministry of Justice agreed that there could be a cost saving by
using a system of fixed penalties, but argued that the saving would be limited (on the basis that
the existing system is efficient and does not involve a significant cost burden to the taxpayer).
Significantly, the Ministry of Justice believes the cost saving would only accrue if evasion
remained at the current level, while anything more than a minimal increase in the rates of
evasion would offset the savings in costs.
201
Set against the fact that cases would be diverted
from the Magistrates’ Court, the court would no longer receive fine revenue and the amount
recovered by TV Licensing through settlements would depend on a number of factors (uptake
of the fixed penalty, recovery of the penalty and level of the fixed penalty). Each of these factors
is addressed below.
Uptake of the fixed penalty
192. Any financial benefit to the taxpayer would be achieved only by diverting a significant number
of offenders from the Magistrates’ Court. If the diversion were ineffective, that is if only a small
number of individuals elected to pay the fixed penalty, the process would add additional cost
and complexity to the process of enforcement with no corresponding benefit. Similarly, if the
evasion level increased and more cases were investigated and prosecuted, the cost to the
taxpayer and licence fee payer would increase. The Voice of the Listener and Viewer
202
argued
that this option risks adding an additional layer of bureaucracy and complexity to the existing
sanctions regime.
199
Andrew Bridgen MP evidence to the Review.
200
BBC consultation response.
201
Ministry of Justice evidence-gathering session.
202
Voice of the Listener and Viewer consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
60
Recovery of the fixed penalty
193. As in the case of Option 3, the recovery rate of the fixed penalty would be an important factor
in the efficient operation of the scheme. Any significant level of default could possibly mean that
enforcement would have to take place, as it does at present, through the Magistrates’ Court.
194. On the basis of the information provided to the Review it cannot be said that moving to a fixed
penalty scheme would necessarily lead to an improvement in the collection rate of penalties,
and there is a risk of reduction in the overall revenue to the taxpayer should the rate of collection
remain static, or if the level of the penalty is set at a level lower than the current average fine.
203
Level of the fixed penalty
195. As with Option 3, the level of the penalty would need to be set at a figure high enough to deter
evasion and cover the running costs of the scheme. At the same time the amount would have
to be reasonable enough to encourage acceptance of the penalty.
204
As the average fine is
currently £170
205
it would have to be lower than this but higher than the level of the current
colour licence fee at £145.50.
206
196. The current penalty tiers in other fixed penalty schemes are generally in the range of £60-£90
and a sum of this magnitude is unlikely to provide an adequate deterrent when set against the
cost of a TV licence. While a higher figure could be set for TV licence offences, this would
involve a fixed monetary penalty considerably higher than those available in most other
comparable schemes.
Deterrence
197. Under the fixed penalty system, while the criminal deterrent remains in place the risk exists that
it will be undermined, although the extent of this risk is linked to the level of the fixed penalty.
Some respondents to the Review were of the opinion that Option 4 retained the deterrent value
of a criminal sanction, given the possibility of instituting a prosecution and in such a scheme
any unpaid penalties would be enforced through the Magistrates’ Court (in the same way as an
unpaid fine).
207
198. Some respondents felt that a lower penalty would impact on public perception of the
seriousness of the offence and may therefore encourage greater evasion. Research conducted
203
Ministry of Justice consultation response: 92% of Fixed Penalty Notices for driving offences were paid in
2012. 51% of all Penalty Notices for Disorder were paid in 2013 with a further 30% registered as fines.
204
Ministry of Justice evidence to the Review. Also supported by Ministry of Justice consultation response.
205
Ministry of Justice consultation response (2013 figures).
206
Ministry of Justice evidence-gathering session: the Ministry of Justice suggested that there is a risk of higher
levels of evasion if the penalty amount were to be set at a figure less than the licence fee.
207
Voice of the Listener and Viewer consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
61
by Harris Interactive which explored whether a scheme similar to that of Option 4
208
would have
an impact on evasion, concluded that evasion could rise from the current rate of 5% to 6%. This
potential increase would cost the BBC an extra £39m in lost revenue.
199. The BBC Trust felt that any move away from the scheme of enforcement as it currently operates
would create a perception that the offence is considered to be ‘less serious’ than was previously
the case and this might lead to an increase in evasion.
209
Additional concerns
200. Some of those who participated in the Review raised additional concerns in relation to the
adoption of Option 4. These issues concerned the possibility of TV Licensing issuing notices
without proper consideration, and fairness to vulnerable individuals.
201. Andrew Bridgen MP and the Centre for Citizenship expressed concerns that TV Licensing might
be tempted to issue penalty notices more freely, or on an inadequate evidential basis, thus
increasing “the possibility that an individual might elect to pay the fixed penalty rather than face
the trouble, expense and embarrassment of a court appearance.”
210
The BBC also expressed
the view that the adoption of Option 4 might ultimately result in more enforcement activity.
202. Both the Ministry of Justice and the Centre for Citizenship raised concerns that the adoption of
this option might lead to a perception on the part of the public that the BBC was using the legal
system as a means of raising revenue (particularly if the number of cases increased).
211
By way
of analogy, the use of parking charge notices has led to some Local Authorities being accused
of profiteering, and it was suggested that the BBC and TV Licensing might be exposed to
damaging allegations of this or a similar nature.
203. One particular difficulty identified with Option 4 is that the fixed monetary penalty has the
potential to impact unfairly on those on lower incomes. The initial penalty is a fixed amount
which cannot be means-tested and the issuer has no discretion in the level of notice
imposed. This is not the case with the existing procedures where the Magistrates’ Court
will take into consideration a range of factors, including ability to pay, when setting the
level of any fine.
212
The fixed penalty system is designed to produce single, one-off payments,
with the result that those on low incomes may not be in a position to avoid prosecution.
208
The Harris Interactive research paper on behavioural changes did not explore specifically a fixed penalty
scheme, but the ‘hybrid’ model is similar enough that we can use it as a proxy. In the Harris hybrid model, first-
time offenders receive a monetary penalty, while multiple offenders are prosecuted through the criminal courts.
This bears a similarity to a fixed monetary penalty scheme, wherein offenders who do not pay the fixed
monetary penalty would be prosecuted through the Magistrates’ Court as under the current process.
209
BBC Trust evidence to the Review.
210
Centre for Citizenship consultation response.
211
Centre for Citizenship consultation response.
212
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
62
204. A number of respondents to the consultation highlighted this as a concern
213
and some felt that
any penalty should be set at a level not to disadvantage those on low incomes
214
there would
otherwise be an incentive to elect prosecution with a view to being sentenced by way of a
means-tested fine.
215
Some members of the public who responded to the consultation felt that
any potential saving in court time was outweighed by the potential impact upon those on low
incomes.
216
For example, Christians Against Poverty felt that this option failed to provide those
in financial difficulty with appropriate assistance, particularly as the penalty would need to be
paid in full within 28 days. The Money Advice Trust response to the consultation highlighted
concerns that this type of system would have a negative impact on those who are unable to
pay.
217
Implementation
205. The implementation of Option 4 would require significant investment. In addition to the
involvement of the BBC, it is likely that Her Majesty’s Courts and Tribunals Service (HMCTS)
would have to process the fixed penalty notices. HMCTS currently processes fixed penalty
notices in four operational units across England and Wales, with 73 full-time (equivalent) staff.
This fields 980,000 compliant (80-85%) notices per year, paying £95m into the Consolidated
Fund.
218
Whilst this is a large scale operation, there is a question of capacity if TV licence fee
offences were to be dealt with through a fixed penalty scheme. In addition the administrative
system for recording fixed penalty notices would require new IT systems with all that entails for
additional set-up costs.
219
TV Licensing enquiry officers would need to be trained in the
operation of the system as they would be required to explain the process and its implications
and carry out the necessary identity checks.
220
Practical considerations: Crown Dependencies
206. In the States of Jersey there is no equivalent of the Regulatory Enforcement and Sanctions Act
2008, and to implement a fixed monetary penalty scheme solely for the purpose of dealing with
the TV licensing offence would require domestic legislation.
221
213
For example, consultation responses of TV Licence Resistance and the Voice of the Listener and Viewer.
214
TV Licence Resistance consultation response.
215
Ministry of Justice evidence-gathering session.
216
Under the Penalty Notice for Disorder scheme, the Ministry of Justice Penalty Notice for Disorder Guidance
(2014) provides that a fixed penalty may not be appropriate where an officer ‘believes the person presents a
considerable risk of not paying the penalty.’ This illustrates the dilemma and the problem of devising a scheme
that operates fairly to all groups.
217
Money Advice Trust consultation response.
218
HMCTS evidence submitted to the Review.
219
Ministry of Justice evidence to the Review.
220
Ministry of Justice Penalty Notice for Disorder Guidance, 2014.
221
Government of Jersey evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
63
207. In the case of the Bailiwick of Guernsey, the option could be implemented by way of local
legislation, but, as the Guernsey authorities made clear, such a penalty would be administered
by and be payable to the Guernsey authorities, not to the Consolidated Fund.
222
Key considerations
208. When judged against the key considerations set out in the Terms of Reference, the
implementation of Option 4 would involve significant operational and investment costs which
would have to be borne by the taxpayer and the licence fee payer. It also carries the risk of
increased evasion. Whilst the use of a fixed penalty notice might otherwise be regarded as a
proportionate response to the problem of licence evasion, it would add an additional layer of
complexity to the enforcement regime and any advantages that might accrue from its
implementation are outweighed by the problems identified above.
Conclusion
209. As in the case of Option 3, Option 4 proceeds on the basis that it would be highly desirable to
divert TV licence fee evaders from the criminal justice system. The difficulty lies in implementing
a scheme that is both fair to all and efficient.
210. On the basis of the evidence available to the Review, the implementation of a fixed penalty
scheme is unlikely to bring any significant improvement to the current system of prosecution
and may in fact create a number of significant practical difficulties.
211. For the reasons set out above and taking into account the key considerations set out in the
Review’s Terms of Reference, the introduction of a fixed penalty scheme would not provide an
effective solution to the problem of TV licence fee evasion. In addition, there is a risk that the
implementation of a fixed penalty scheme would become outdated as a result of any changes
made to the licence fee collection model, following the forthcoming Charter Review.
222
Government of Guernsey evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
64
3e. OPTION 5
Civil monetary penalty: decriminalise and enforce via a civil infraction.
212. Option 5 involves the repeal of the TV licence evasion offence, the creation of a statutory
obligation to have a TV licence and enforcement of this obligation through the imposition of a
civil monetary penalty.
213. A civil monetary penalty is neither a fine nor a criminal conviction: it is instead a penalty for
failing to comply with a statutory obligation.
214. Civil monetary penalties are currently levied in the case of parking, congestion charging and
bus lane contravention. By way of example, Local Authorities are vested with the power to issue
monetary penalties (known as penalty charge notices) to individuals who contravene parking
regulations. Following receipt of the notice, individuals have 28 days in which to pay the amount
claimed, but may receive a reduction for early payment (usually if payment is made within 14
days).
223
215. Under Option 5, if the penalty remained unpaid it would be treated as a civil debt. An individual
would have the opportunity to make an informal challenge to the notice and if unsuccessful, the
individual would have a right of appeal and it is envisaged that this appeal would be to an
independent adjudicator. Enforcement of the penalty would take place in the civil court system
and thus would involve conventional methods of enforcement, such as the employment of
bailiffs, seizure of property, and the use of attachment of earnings and charging orders.
Overview
216. The attraction of the civil monetary penalty is that it would involve the decriminalisation of licence
fee evasion and the removal of all TV licence fee evasion cases from the criminal courts. The
problems associated with Option 5 arise from the radical nature of the change from criminal to
civil enforcement. The principal difficulties are threefold. First, the possible risk of increased
evasion (as a result of the removal of the criminal deterrent); second, the investment costs
involved in establishing a system of civil enforcement; and third, the operational costs involved
in recovering what are likely to be small or even nominal amounts of debt. During the course of
the Review concerns were also expressed about the possible impact on low income
households. The BBC argued that, as TV Licensing would be responsible for the process of
enforcement, this might bring about a change in the relationship between the BBC and the
public.
223
Traffic Management Act 2004; Civil Enforcement of Parking Contraventions (England) General Regulations
2007.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
65
217. In addition to the difficulties identified by contributors to the Review, the mechanism for
collecting the licence fee may be altered as a result of the forthcoming Charter Review, and
such a scheme might well become outdated even before it has had time to prove its worth.
218. Of all the options, Options 5 and 6 had the least support from those who contributed to the
Review and we have concluded that decriminalisation is not a viable alternative to the current
system of enforcement, at least under the current system of licence fee collection.
219. In the paragraphs that follow we discuss the merits or otherwise of implementing Option 5
having regard to the evidence available to the Review and the key considerations contained in
the Terms of Reference.
Discussion
220. There was little support for this option among those who contributed to the Review, although
John Whittingdale MP and Andrew Bridgen MP drew our attention to the fact that there is
support within Parliament for a civil enforcement regime. Furthermore, they pointed out that the
Deregulation Act 2015 provides that no change to the current system is to be implemented
before April 2017,
224
and this would provide sufficient time for an orderly implementation to take
place.
221. The principal attraction of Option 5 is that it would remove all TV licence fee evasion cases from
the criminal justice system. As noted above, the use of imprisonment as the ultimate sanction
for non-payment of a fine (originating from failure to hold a TV licence) is seen by many as a
failing of the present system, so the move to a civil system of enforcement was seen by some
consultation respondents as a positive step. A statutory obligation to pay the licence fee coupled
with a system of debt recovery was felt by some members of the public to be a more
proportionate response to the problem of licence fee evasion. As licence fee evasion would be
removed from the court system, resort to court proceedings would only be necessary in the
event of non-payment. Set against this, the County Court would assume responsibility for
dealing with claims for recovery of the debt and TV Licensing would be required to assume
responsibility for enforcement. The Ministry of Justice, in its evidence to the Review, stated that
in each calendar year, the County Court manages over a million similar types of money claim
(a claim for a fixed amount of money) and has in place efficient systems for dealing with multiple
applications of claims of a similar nature.
222. TV Licence Resistance argued in its consultation response that if “done correctly”, there could
be some merit to the implementation of Option 5, “especially if the reform takes account of the
issues with obtaining evidence of evasion, and imposes upon the BBC an independent appeals
body (which could also help address the issue of non-accountability)”.
225
TV Licence Resistance
also felt that, under the current system, the threat of court appearances and criminal offence is
224
Deregulation Act 2015, section 78 (ii).
225
TV Licence Resistance consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
66
“exploited” by the BBC, and a benefit of this option would be to remove “opportunities for threat
and misinformation.
226
223. Treating the licence fee as a civil debt would provide some savings to the taxpayer, who would
not be required to meet the costs of the civil proceedings. On the other hand, the cost to the
licence fee payer is likely to increase significantly, for reasons explained below.
224. Criticism of Option 5 came from a number of respondents who noted that the removal of criminal
sanctions would not necessarily be an improvement. The BBC argued that enforcement
mechanisms would include the use of debt collection agencies and the use of bailiffs (whereas
in the current system the use of bailiffs appears to be rare and their use is controlled by the
court
227
).
228
The Money Advice Trust echoed these concerns and contended that this model
represented “the worst of both worlds.
229
The Voice of the Listener and Viewer argued that the
civil enforcement system could be seen as “more punitive than the current system which leaves
an offender with neither a centrally-recorded criminal offence [sic] nor a reduced ability to borrow
money.
225. Several contributors to the Review argued that the move to a civil system would be complex
and costly. It would require legislation and would require TV Licensing to change its operational
practices to a very considerable extent.
226. There are also some practical implementation issues for the Crown Dependencies. The
Government of Jersey noted that an independent appeals body would need to be established
for cases within Jersey.
230
The Government of Guernsey also expressed reservations about the
practicality of this option because it would require the establishment of an appeals body within
each of the constituent parts of the Bailiwick (i.e. Alderney, Sark and Guernsey).
231
227. It was also argued that the use of a civil process could “result in much larger numbers of
households and businesses being penalised for licence fee evasion.
232
,
233
226
TV Licence Resistance consultation response.
227
Ministry of Justice Freedom of Information Request, Outstanding Court Fines for HMCTS
https://www.justice.gov.uk/downloads/information-access-rights/foi-disclosure-log/courts-tribunals/outstanding-
court-fines.doc.
228
BBC consultation response.
229
Money Advice Trust consultation response.
230
Government of Jersey evidence to the Review.
231
Government of Guernsey evidence to the Review.
232
BBC consultation response.
233
Both the BBC and TV Licence Resistance raised concerns about the fact that this is a lower threshold, and
could lead to an increase in the number of evasion cases: for example, those who have let their licence expire
and are delaying a renewal could reasonably be assessed as still requiring a licence on the balance of
probabilities, whereas under the current system there would be an investigation and assessment before
prosecution (which would involve opportunities to buy a licence to avoid prosecution).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
67
228. Other respondents raised concerns about the potential negative impacts on an individual’s
credit rating. For example, the BBC Trust suggested that this could be a very damaging
consequence for some people which could have lasting repercussions for their financial
security. Set against this, Callcredit
234
argued that the scheme might actually help to prevent
individuals from falling into debt.
235
Deterrence
229. A consistent theme expressed in the course of the Review was that a civil enforcement system
would be likely to have a reduced deterrent effect (compared to the current system of
enforcement) and that this would have a detrimental effect on compliance with the obligation to
hold a TV licence. The risk of an increased level of evasion under a civil model was emphasised
in an expert consultation response
236
and the research commissioned by the BBC suggests that
the existence of a criminal offence is in itself a strong factor in deterring evasion (with 54%
purchasing a licence ‘because it’s the law’ or ‘it’s illegal not to’).
237
The same research
suggested that evasion rates would increase significantly under a civil model as they are less
effective at making people pay.
238
230. Several of those who contributed to the Review cited the experience of licence fee
decriminalisation in Japan, where evasion rates rose to 25% (though it is to be noted that this
coincided with a number of high profile scandals at the public service broadcaster, which may
also have contributed to the scale of evasion).
239
231. The issue of deterrence is also linked to the scale of any civil penalty. It would have to be set at
a level high enough to deter evasion, while at the same time low enough to encourage
acceptance at an early stage of the enforcement process. The Harris Interactive behavioural
research study found that at all levels of monetary penalty tested - including £500,
approximately 3 times the current average fine - evasion remained higher under a civil model
than under the current model (5%), although the difference is more pronounced and grows more
rapidly at lower levels, suggesting that under a civil penalty model the level of penalty would
have to increase in order to keep evasion at a similar rate to current levels.
240
This could have
an unfair impact on those on low incomes and state benefits.
234
Callcredit Information Group, a consumer data group comprising a number of companies including
Callcredit, a UK credit reference agency.
235
Callcredit consultation response.
236
Patrick Barwise consultation response; Mr Barwise is a leading figure in marketing and consumer
representation, and contributed to one of the Review’s evidence-gathering sessions.
237
Harris Interactive Behavioural Research, BBC consultation response.
238
Harris Interactive Behavioural Research.
239
This was also discussed in the Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee’s 2015 ‘Future of the BBC’
report: http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201415/cmselect/cmcumeds/315/315.pdf.
240
The Harris Interactive study is reviewed in more detail at Annex E.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
68
232. The BBC estimates a doubling in the financial impact of evasion under a civil enforcement
regime, from the current level of around £213m to £409m.
241
The BBC Executive, in the course
of its evidence to the Review, raised concerns that the likely increased evasion rate and
subsequent costs meant that “a civil model could lead to a sense of unfairness amongst licence
fee payers”,
242
a view echoed by a respected academic.
243
The Producers’ Alliance for Cinema
and Television (PACT)
244
agreed that increased costs to the BBC under this model would have
a negative impact on the BBC’s ability to invest in programme content, and would therefore
represent worse value for money for licence fee payers.
245
233. The Scottish Courts and Tribunals Service voiced concerns over the administrative costs that
this option would impose, estimating that bringing small claims to courts in place of their existing
fiscal fine system would result in a 44% increase in the number of small claims representing
additional court and judicial staff costs of £211,000 annually.
246
234. This system would also require the establishment of an independent appeals body, the set-up
and administration costs of which would be passed on to the taxpayer or licence fee payer.
235. The Government of Guernsey suggested that legal fees incurred by TV Licensing in pursuing
cases within the Bailiwick courts would vastly outweigh the likely amounts recovered.
Low income households
236. A number of consultation responses raised concerns about the impact that implementation of
Option 5 might have on low income households. It was argued that while it would be possible
to discount the amount payable in return for early settlement, immediate payment even of the
discounted amount may not be feasible for certain members of the community.
237. The organisation Christians Against Poverty was critical of the possible impact on those who
struggle with debts and the limited amount of time within which to make a payment. It was felt
that this could result in escalating debts and that the “regime would still penalise those on low
income [sic] and in financial difficulty, and would not include the flexibility needed to show
adequate forbearance and sensitivity.
247
Comparison with utility bills
238. A number of respondents to the Review questioned the comparison between non-payment of
utility bills and non-payment of the licence fee. While it is correct that non-payment of utility bills
241
This figure is based on behavioural research commissioned from Harris Interactive, which forecasts that
under a civil model evasion would rise to 9%. (Harris Interactive Behavioural Research).
242
BBC consultation response.
243
Patrick Barwise consultation response.
244
PACT, a trade association representing independent UK television and film companies.
245
PACT consultation response.
246
Scottish Courts and Tribunals Service consultation response.
247
Christians Against Poverty consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
69
such as gas, electricity and water is treated as a civil debt, unlike these utilities, TV Licensing is
not able to install a pre-payment meter or disconnect a non-payer’s supply and so would not
have a ‘final option’ with which to encourage payment before resorting to enforcement activities.
Conditional access technology
239. During the course of the Review, we explored whether the use of conditional access technology
could go some way to reducing the risks of evasion if a civil system were to be introduced.
However, Lord Grade informed us that conditional access technology is not sufficiently
advanced to make this feasible and it will be some years before suitable equipment is developed
to enable broadcasters to control access to their programmes in a suitable manner.
Enforcement difficulties
240. The Ministry of Justice suggested that this type of civil penalty arrangement was not ideally
suited to TV licence fee enforcement. This arises because of the difficulty of establishing
evasion (which would be necessary to prove the existence of the debt), particularly if TV
Licensing did not have those powers of investigation (such as the availability of search warrants)
available under the current regime.
Other concerns
241. The BBC raised concerns about a potential conflict of interest in its operations, in that it would
be responsible for collecting evidence, deciding on whether to apply a penalty, and pursuing
the civil action.
248
While this would be balanced by the creation of an independent adjudicator
to manage appeals, it nevertheless represents a significant increase in TV Licensing’s role and
responsibilities.
242. The BBC Trust shared concerns that where the penalty was not paid it would have to be pursued
through the civil courts as a civil debt, and this would require the BBC to initiate proceedings
and pursue them through to enforcement. There is a concern that this would alter the BBC’s
relationship with the public and be damaging to its image and reputation.
243. The Ministry of Justice and the Centre for Citizenship raised concerns that this system could
lead to a perception that the BBC was using the legal system as a means to raise revenues
(particularly if the number of cases increased).
249
By way of analogy, the use of parking charge
notices has led to some Local Authorities being accused of profiteering, and it would be
undesirable to expose the BBC and TV Licensing to allegations of this or a similar nature.
244. The principal objections to the adoption of Option 5 were the costs of establishing a new system
of civil enforcement, the costs involved in collecting the debt and the risk that the level of evasion
would increase. Concerns over the costs of a civil option were expressed during evidence
248
BBC consultation response.
249
Centre for Citizenship consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
70
sessions by the Ministry of Justice, the BBC Trust and the BBC Executive. In their consultation
response the BBC noted that this model would “increase licence fee evasion and collection
costs, likely significantly, reducing value for money for both licence fee payers and taxpayers.”
The BBC argued that in the event of non-payment the debtor would be pursued by the civil
claimant (the BBC), with the result that the BBC would be liable for all the costs of the
proceedings as well as the costs of enforcement. The BBC (supported by The Voice of the
Listener and Viewer) contended that the collection of civil penalties would be both expensive
and difficult to achieve. Of particular concern was the commercial benefit of pursuing certain
cases, with the result that a certain level of evasion might be tolerated or written off, on the
grounds that enforcement was simply not cost-effective.
250
Key considerations
245. Having regard to the key considerations as set out in the Terms of Reference, and having taken
into account the evidence available to the Review, it is apparent that the implementation of
Option 5 would involve significant investment costs and lead to an increase in operational costs.
These costs would be borne by the licence fee payer and the taxpayer. It would also carry the
risk of a rise in the rate of evasion with a corresponding loss of revenue to the BBC. While a
move to a civil system of enforcement may be desirable in the long term, the implementation of
such a system under the current system of licence fee collection would be neither efficient nor
effective.
Conclusion
246. Option 5 had only limited support from those who contributed to the Review. The evidence we
have examined suggests that the implementation of a civil monetary penalty would not be
feasible under the current system of licence fee collection. Accordingly, we have concluded that
Option 5 would not provide a viable mechanism for the efficient and fair disposal of TV licence
evasion cases.
250
In its consultation response the BBC made reference to fact that the DVLA has written off around one-third
of penalties for non-renewal of vehicle tax because they were too difficult to collect (and of the two thirds that
were pursued, less than half were paid). The DVLA Annual Report and Accounts confirms that in 2010/11 it
collected £31m fine and penalty income (of £49m gross collectable) and wrote off £18m (36.73%).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
71
3f. OPTION 6
Civil debt: decriminalise and enforce as a civil debt.
247. Option 6 would involve treating the licence fee as a civil debt recoverable through the civil courts.
This is currently the position in the case of non-payment of utility bills, where, as a matter of last
resort, the debtor may be proceeded against in the County Court where, if liability is proved, an
order may be obtained requiring payment of the debt.
Overview
248. The arguments against the implementation of this option were similar to those advanced against
Option 5; the risk of increased evasion and cost. Under a civil system of enforcement, TV
Licensing would bear the burden of costs, including the costs of enforcement, unless and until
they were recovered from the defendant at the conclusion of the civil proceedings.
249. It was also pointed out that the analogy with non-payment of utility bills is not altogether apt: the
TV licence is not a payment for services and if this option were to be implemented it would
require legislation to characterise the licence fee as a civil debt. One of the key difficulties
associated with Option 6 is that TV Licensing would only be able to bring proceedings to recover
the debt attributable to the period of evasion, which would have to be established by satisfactory
proof. The consequence of this is that the amount owing might only be a small or nominal sum
and in many cases it would make no commercial sense to pursue the case to court.
250. In addition to the difficulties identified by contributors to the Review, the mechanism for
collecting the licence fee may be the subject of change following the Charter Review, and such
a scheme might well become outdated even before it has had time to prove its worth.
251. It was for these principal reasons that we made no recommendations in relation to Option 6.
252. In the paragraphs that follow we discuss the merits or otherwise of implementing Option 6
having regard to the evidence available to the Review and the key considerations contained in
the Terms of Reference.
Discussion
253. As in the case of Option 5, there was little support for this option among those who contributed
to the Review, although John Whittingdale MP and Andrew Bridgen MP drew our attention to
the fact that there is support within Parliament for a civil enforcement regime. Furthermore,
they pointed out that the Deregulation Act 2015 provides that no change to the current system
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
72
is to be implemented before April 2017,
251
and this would provide sufficient time for
implementation to take place.
254. A civil system of debt recovery was felt by a number of consultation respondents to be a more
proportionate response to the problem of TV licence evasion and for many individual
respondents the removal of the possibility of imprisonment would be a positive step.
252
255. Christians Against Poverty described Option 6 as “the most appropriate, fair and cost-effective”
option, noting good practice established in the consumer credit industry which could be used to
inform fair collection activity. It was also argued that Option 6 provides “adequate opportunities
for people to dispute the debt or accept their liability and arrange payment before court
action and enforcement agent fees are incurred.” However it was also noted that “if unpaid
licence fees were liable for statutory interest and charges, monetary penalties could
escalate quickly and become unaffordable.”
253
256. Though it had concerns with each of the options, the Money Advice Trust
254
cited this option as
“the least punitive approach” for those struggling to manage their debts wisely, particularly as
County Courts were seen as being well able to deal with debt repayment issues (such as
payment by instalments).
255
The fact that this system might have a negative impact on an
evader’s credit rating was seen by Callcredit as a potentially positive step, as it would help to
protect individuals from getting into debt in the future. Callcredit also suggested that were TV
licence fee payment information to be shared as part of an individual’s credit rating, this could
have the positive benefit of building the credit rating of those “people who currently pay their TV
licences as required, yet find it difficult to secure mainstream and lower cost credit and banking
facilities.”
256
257. It was also argued that the BBC would have more options through which to pursue non-
payment, for example by the use of bailiffs.
258. The Government of Jersey noted that in terms of implementation this would be the least
problematic of the alternative options.
257
251
Deregulation Act 2015, section 78 (ii).
252
As discussed under Option 1, we believe that the current system is more fair and proportionate than it is
perceived to be, and the existence of the criminal is not disproportionate. Nor is the use of imprisonment to
enforce court-imposed fines. Furthermore, non-payment of a number of civil debts (including Council Tax) can
also be enforced by imprisonment.
253
Christians Against Poverty consultation response.
254
A debt advice charity.
255
Money Advice Trust consultation response.
256
Callcredit consultation response, 2015.
257
Government of Jersey evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
73
Deterrence
259. Set against these points, it was argued that the process of moving from a criminal to a civil
system of enforcement could create the impression that non-payment of the licence fee is now
regarded as being less important, thus increasing the risk of evasion. The BBC cited research
suggesting that the existence of a criminal offence is in itself a strong factor in deterring evasion
(with 54% purchasing a licence ‘because it’s the law’ or ‘it’s illegal not to’).
258
The same research
suggested that that evasion rates would increase significantly under a civil model.
259
260. The BBC Executive raised concerns that the likely increased evasion rate and subsequent costs
meant that “a civil model could lead to a sense of unfairness amongst licence fee payers”, a
point echoed by one of the experts who contributed to the Review.
260
Costs
261. In addition to the increased risk of evasion, concerns surrounding the costs of moving to a civil
system were expressed by the Ministry of Justice, the BBC Trust and the BBC Executive. In its
consultation response the BBC noted that a civil model would “increase licence fee evasion and
collection costs, likely significantly, reducing value for money for both licence fee payers and
taxpayers.” Concerns were raised by the BBC (echoed by The Voice of the Listener and Viewer)
that the collection of civil debts would be both expensive and difficult to achieve, which could
raise questions about the benefit of pursuing certain cases and put the BBC in a position of
having to write off a certain level of evasion on the grounds that enforcing would not be cost-
effective.
261
PACT warned that the increased costs to the BBC under this model would have a
negative impact on the BBC’s ability to invest in programme content, and would therefore
represent worse value for money for licence fee payers.
262. The Scottish Courts and Tribunals Service voiced concern over the administrative costs that
this option would impose, estimating that bringing small claims to courts in place of their existing
fiscal fine system would result in a 44% increase in the number of small claims and represent
additional court and judicial staff costs of £211,000 annually.
262
263. The Government of Guernsey suggested that legal fees incurred by the BBC in pursuing cases
within the Bailiwick courts would vastly outweigh the amounts likely to be recovered.
258
Harris Interactive Behavioural Research & BBC consultation response.
259
Harris Interactive Behavioural Research.
260
Patrick Barwise consultation response.
261
If evasion were to rise, the financial impact on the BBC would be significant (around £39m for each 1%
increase in evasion) and value for money for the licence fee payer greatly reduced.
262
Scottish Courts and Tribunal Service consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
74
Comparison with utility bills
264. A number of respondents to the Review questioned the comparison between non-payment of
utility bills and non-payment of the licence fee. While it is correct that non-payment of utility bills
such as gas, electricity and water is treated as a civil debt, unlike these utilities TV Licensing
does not have the ability to install a pre-payment meter or disconnect a non-payer’s supply and
so would not have a ‘final option’ with which to encourage payment before resorting to
enforcement activities.
Other concerns
265. The BBC Trust suggested that the impact of a civil debt system could be very damaging for
some individuals, with the potential for lasting repercussions on their financial security.
266. It was also suggested that the use of civil proceedings would make the approach to enforcement
less targeted and “result in much larger numbers of households and businesses being penalised
for licence fee evasion.
263
,
264
In civil proceedings evasion would only need to be proved on the
balance of probabilities”, whereas criminal proceedings are brought only where the tests in the
Code for Crown Prosecutors are satisfied and, where a prosecution is brought, the offence must
be proved beyond reasonable doubt.
267. The BBC argued that without the powers of investigation currently available under the criminal
regime (such as the availability of search warrants) the investigation of evasion would become
more difficult. It was also suggested that the BBC’s role in enforcing the debt carries the risk of
damaging the BBC’s relationship with the public.
268. The BBC Trust echoed this concern and argued that by assuming the responsibility of
enforcement from the state the BBC would have to become a different kind of agency, and this
had the potential to damage its relationship with the public, particularly if it were perceived to
be institutionally unsympathetic. The BBC also raised concerns about the potential conflict of
interest that could arise from its responsibilities for collecting evidence, pursuing civil action and
enforcing the debt.
Practical considerations
269. One of the key difficulties inherent in Option 6 is that in order to enforce a civil debt, the BBC
would have to provide evidence of the period of time for which the individual had been
unlicensed, and the amount of the debt would be in a sum corresponding to the period of
evasion. It would be difficult to prove the period of unlicensed use with the result that the amount
of the debt is likely to be small or nominal.
263
BBC consultation response.
264
Both the BBC and TV Licence Resistance raised concerns that this option could lead to an increase in
enforcement activity.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
75
270. It would of course be possible to legislate for an assumed figure to be the amount recoverable,
as is the case with Vehicle Excise Duty, where liability is backdated to the expiry of the last
excise licence.
265
However, to adopt such a scheme in the case of the TV licence fee would
present real difficulties, particularly as parts of the unlicensed period may have been legally
unlicensed. TV Licence Resistance maintains that “any form of automatic assumption about the
length of time for which a household was unlicensed would be intrinsically unfair either because
TV might not have been watched during some or all of the unlicensed period, or responsibility
for the licence may have changed (possibly informally) during the unlicensed period.
271. The Ministry of Justice identified this inability to establish the period of evasion to a satisfactory
level of proof as the major issue for pursuing enforcement via a civil debt and felt it would be
unfeasible without using a ‘stand-in’, which would be considered unfair.
266
272. The Government of Jersey noted that there are no private sector bailiffs operating within Jersey,
and that there have been recent difficulties in the enforcement of small debts within their
jurisdiction.
Key considerations
273. Having regard to the key considerations in the Terms of Reference and based on the evidence
available to the Review, the implementation of Option 6 would involve significant operational
costs and investment which would be borne by the licence fee payer and the taxpayer. It would
also carry the risk of a rise in the rate of evasion with a corresponding loss of revenue to the
BBC. While a move to a civil system of enforcement may be desirable in the long term, the
implementation of such a system under the current system of licence fee collection would be
neither efficient nor effective.
Conclusion
274. Option 6 had only limited support from those who contributed to the Review. The evidence we
have examined suggests that the implementation of a scheme of civil debt enforcement would
not be feasible under the current system of licence fee collection. The principal objections arise
from the potential cost, especially the cost to the licence fee payer of the costs of enforcement
and a possible rise in evasion. Accordingly, we have concluded that Option 6 would not provide
a viable mechanism for the efficient and fair disposal of TV licence evasion cases.
265
Vehicle Excise and Registration Act 1994, section 31.
266
Ministry of Justice evidence-gathering session.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
76
Chapter 4: Other Options for Change
Culture, Media and Sport Committee Recommendations
275. The Culture, Media and Sport Committee (CMS) is a Parliamentary Select Committee which
oversees the work of the Department for Culture, Media and Sport. In February 2015 it published
a report entitled ‘Future of the BBC’. This wide-ranging and detailed report, based on a year-
long evidence-gathering process, contains a helpful discussion of matters relevant to the
forthcoming review of the BBC’s Royal Charter, including the future of the licence fee and
decriminalisation of licence fee evasion.
276. The clear view of the CMS Committee is that the current criminal offence is overdue for reform
and licence evasion should be decriminalised. The CMS Committee acknowledged, however,
that decriminalisation is not feasible under the current model of licence fee collection as it would
carry an increased risk of evasion and possible significant loss of revenue to the BBC. On the
question of reform, the CMS Committee concluded that any change in the enforcement regime
should be tied to reform of the funding mechanism which might involve, for example, a move to
a broadcasting levy or the introduction of controls governing access to television broadcasts.
277. While this Review has reached the same overall conclusion as the CMS Committee, it has done
so for different reasons. The CMS Committee concluded that decriminalisation is necessary in
order to address the unfairness of the current system and that a change in the licence fee
collection model would facilitate this reform. By way of contrast, this Review has concluded that
the current enforcement regime is more fair and proportionate than is generally supposed. The
weight of the evidence provided to the Review also suggests that decriminalisation, which
appears at first sight to be an attractive step, would have significant cost implications to the
licence fee payer and taxpayer, at least in the short term.
278. We agree that if changes are to be made to the method by which the licence fee is collected,
then the balance is likely to tilt in favour of decriminalisation. That said, any reform of the licence
fee collection model is a matter for the Secretary of State to consider in light of the forthcoming
Charter Review and any conclusions reached as a result of that Review.
279. To the extent that some of the issues raised in the CMS Committee report touch upon the
current Review, these are addressed in the following paragraphs.
280. The CMS Committee concluded: “the justification for criminal penalties for non-payment
of the TV licence fee and the way TV licensing enforcement is carried out is anachronistic
and out of proportion with responses to non-payment for other services.”
267
267
‘Future of the BBC’, Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee 2015, p3:
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201415/cmselect/cmcumeds/315/315.pdf.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
77
281. This was a view shared by some of those who gave evidence to the Review. However, the
evidence we have received justifies the use of a criminal sanction for licence evasion. As the
CMS Committee appears to have acknowledged, the current system of licence fee collection
requires the existence of a powerful deterrent in the overall public interest. In the case of the
TV licence, there is no mechanism for the removal of broadcasting services from non-payers.
282. These considerations apart, the CMS Committee has provided a powerfully reasoned argument
that the criminal sanction is likely to become unnecessary if reform of the funding model
removed the need for a criminal deterrent.
283. The CMS Committee also acknowledged: “...the possibility, based on the evidence
presented and international experience, that decriminalisation could lead to an increase
in evasion and potentially, therefore, a reduction in the BBC's income.
268
284. This is also one of the conclusions reached by this Review and the weight of the evidence
supports the concern expressed by the CMS Committee. This Review has also concluded that
the increased costs of implementing and enforcing a civil option would have significant adverse
financial implications for the taxpayer and licence fee payer, and that for these reasons the two
decriminalisation options (Options 5 and 6) are impractical under the current system of licence
fee collection. The removal of powers of investigation currently available to the BBC under the
criminal regime would also make the BBC’s investigatory role more difficult, and the BBC’s role
in enforcing the civil penalty or civil debt would carry the risk of damaging the BBC’s relationship
with the public.
285. The CMS Committee expressed a belief that “there is a strong case for making non-
payment a civil matter pursued through the civil courts in the same way as non-payment
of council tax, parking fines and utility bills.”
269
286. The weight of the evidence provided to the Review supports the Committee’s conclusion that
decriminalisation is not feasible under the current licence fee collection model.
287. The analogy with utility bills has been addressed earlier; the short point is that the enforcement
of amounts owing to utility companies is much simpler than enforcing the requirement to hold a
TV licence, where the period of unlicensed viewing is difficult to establish and there is no ability
to meter or remove the availability of access to television broadcasts.
288. Non-payment of council tax is enforced by the Local Authority applying for a liability order from
the Magistrates' Court. The Local Authority can then seek to recover the debt by reductions
from wages or benefits or by using bailiffs. Imprisonment is also available as a sanction for
non-payment council tax.
270
268
‘Future of the BBC’, Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee 2015, p79, par 224.
269
‘Future of the BBC’, Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee 2015, p122, par 40.
270
Council Tax (Administration and Enforcement) Regulations 1992, part VI.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
78
289. The BBC’s consultation response noted that non-payment of council tax led to the imprisonment
of 107 people in 2012, whereas for non-payment of a fine relating to TV licence fee the figure
was 51 (which in 2013 had fallen to 32).
271
Additionally, moving to a civil system would involve
increased enforcement costs, which would have to be met by licence fee payers.
290. One of the suggestions made by the CMS Committee was that: decriminalisation of the
licence fee could be linked to introducing controls for access to television services or
moving to a German-style broadcasting levy.
272
291. It is apparent that the CMS Committee linked the issue of decriminalisation of licence fee
evasion to other mechanisms that would remove the risk of evasion or make the licence fee
easier to collect. The type of funding model that might eventually be adopted is beyond the
scope of this Review and will fall to be considered in the forthcoming review of the BBC’s Royal
Charter. It is to be noted, however, that a move to a universal broadcasting levy would meet
many of the concerns that currently stand in the way of reform.
Conclusion
292. The CMS Committee conducted a thorough and carefully reasoned review of the future of the
BBC. The Committee and this Review have reached the same overall conclusion:
decriminalisation of licence evasion, while ultimately a desirable aim, is not a feasible option
under the current licence fee system.
271
BBC consultation response. Figures updated using Magistrates' Court volume statistics provided to the
Review by the Ministry of Justice.
272
The German equivalent of the licence fee is a universal broadcasting levy which requires all households to
pay a charge, regardless of whether or how they consume broadcasting services (with some concessions).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
79
Chapter 5: Conclusions and Next Steps
Conclusion
293. This Review recommends no fundamental change in the sanctions regime under the
current licence fee model. The current regime represents a broadly fair and proportionate
response to the problem of licence fee evasion and provides good value for both the licence fee
payer and taxpayer. Within the constraints of the current licence fee collection system, there is
no practical alternative that will work as efficiently and effectively.
294. There is some scope, however, to improve the current system and these improvements will go
some way to meeting the concerns arising from the operation of the current regime, particularly
in relation to the transparency of the prosecution process and tone of TV Licensing’s
communications.
295. A full list of recommendations can be found in the Executive Summary.
Future Considerations
296. Although the principal recommendation is for the criminal offence to remain as it is, a number
of issues have arisen for consideration during the course of the Review. These issues would
benefit from consideration in the forthcoming review of the BBC’s Royal Charter.
Funding model
297. It has been concluded that the strong deterrent value of the criminal offence is required because
of the structure of the current licence fee funding model. In the event of changes being made to
the model, it would be desirable to reconsider whether the criminal offence remains necessary.
298. It is beyond the scope of this Review to express any views on the shape that an alternative
funding model might take. It does, however, seem reasonable to suggest that future reviews
should give consideration to the complexity of the licensing framework. It should be capable of
being easily understood by the public. Removing the confusion that has built up over the years
through technological advances and an increasing number of regulations would be desirable.
One element in particular that seems overdue for change would be to remove from the licence
any reference to “television”. The licence covers many different aspects of broadcasting and
this should be reflected in how it is styled.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
80
Recommendation 8:
When considering the structure of licence fee collection as part of the forthcoming
Charter Review, a move towards a simpler system would assist in improving public
understanding of what the licence fee covers.
Non-linear viewing
299. Another issue which falls outside the scope of this Review, but which has an increasing impact
on the viability of the current scheme of licensing, is non-linear viewing.
273
As discussed under
Option 1, non-linear, or non-live, viewing allows an increasing number of people legally to
access television broadcasts without a licence, and places an increasing burden on the licence
fee payer.
Recommendation 9:
The Charter Review should look at non-linear viewing as a matter of urgency.
Consideration should be given to the inclusion of non-linear viewing within the licence
fee framework.
Next Steps
300. This report will be presented to Ministers of the Department for Culture, Media and Sport for
their consideration. The Secretary of State will lay the report before both Houses of Parliament
and it will be presented to the BBC Trust. In accordance with section 77 of the Deregulation Act
2015,
274
the Secretary of State will set out the response and steps to be taken within three
months of the Review being completed.
273
Linear viewing refers to traditional television broadcasting. Non-linear viewing refers to viewing of TV
programmes after they have been broadcast, for example by recording using DVR, or streaming via the internet
using Video on Demand services such as BBC iPlayer.
274
Deregulation Act 2015.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
81
ANNEX A: TERMS OF REFERENCE REVIEW OF TV LICENCE FEE ENFORCEMENT
Background
A television licence is required in order to watch all live or nearly-live broadcast television content on
any device in the UK. The BBC is tasked with collection of the licence lee, a function currently
subcontracted to a private company under the brand ‘TV Licensing’. Failure to hold a TV licence when
required is an offence under section 363 of the Communications Act 2003, punishable by a fine of up
to £1000.
1. Objectives
a. To conduct a review into the enforcement regime for failure to have a TV licence, to:
examine whether the sanctions for contravening this offence are appropriate, fair
and whether the regime represents value for money for licence fee payers and
taxpayers; and
identify and assess options for amending the current enforcement regime,
including those for decriminalisation of TV Licensing offences, and whether
these options would represent an improvement, based on the key considerations
below (2a-e).
b. To make recommendations to the Government by the end of June 2015
2. Key considerations
In assessing the objectives above (1a b), the review will consider the following factors:
a. Value for money for licence fee payers and taxpayers in enforcement of the failure to
have a TV licence, including operational, revenue and investment costs of the
enforcement regime to the BBC and to the court system.
b. Fairness for all licence fee payers, and effectiveness in deterring evasion.
c. Proportionality and ease of enforcement.
d. Degree to which the regime is easy to understand by all.
e. Where appropriate, practical considerations for effective transition from the current
regime to a different one.
3. Process
The review should seek evidence from a wide range of stakeholders, including the public, the BBC,
Government stakeholders, the courts, and other interested parties.
4. Output
A report setting out an assessment of the current and proposed enforcement regimes, key findings,
conclusions and any other supporting information to be submitted to the Government by the end
of June 2015. The Secretary of State will lay this report before both Houses of Parliament and it
will be presented to the BBC Trust.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
82
ANNEX B: COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS
This document is intended to provide qualitative and quantitative analysis to inform the final report of
the TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review. It is an updated version of Annex B of the consultation
document, which contained a provisional analysis.
This updated cost-benefit analysis contains information, gathered prior to and during the consultation
period, which has helped to inform the Review’s final recommendations.
There remain some costs and benefits which have not been possible to quantify and where this is the
case these are set out in qualitative terms.
Methodology
Basis of analysis
The foundation of the analysis is the process underlying each option, from investigation and
prosecution to outcome. The process for each option has distinctive costs and benefits: by estimating
these at each point we can build a picture of the overall net impact of the options to each affected
group. The groups primarily affected are the Government (of each jurisdiction), the BBC
275
, and the
licence fee evader (the individual). Business licence fee payers are affected but to a much lesser
extent, and therefore for simplicity we have focused our analysis on the individual or household
licence fee payer.
Evasion rate and the number of people prosecuted
A crucial underlying figure for the analysis is the evasion rate and the number of individuals
prosecuted for TV licence evasion. The current rate of evasion in the UK is around 5%.
276
This
equates to approximately £200m of lost income to the BBC, based on the current level of the licence
fee at £145.50.
277
Between 2010 and 2012, the number of individuals prosecuted averaged just over
150,000.
278
For the purpose of this analysis we assume that the evasion rate and the number of
prosecutions will stay constant over time, in the absence of any changes to enforcement.
Each of the alternative options involves changes in the way evaders are investigated, prosecuted or
penalised. Annex E provides a brief review of the literature regarding the relationship between
changes to the formulation of the law and crime rates. It also includes an analysis of the research
produced by Harris Interactive for the BBC. Having carried out quality assurance on the Harris
Interactive research we have used their findings to inform assumptions about how evasion rates
might change under each option.
The Harris Research used discrete choice modelling to estimate the evasion rates for three models
current, civil, and hybrid. The ‘current’ model was designed to resemble the current system. The ‘civil’
model assumes a flat fine for anyone without a television licence after 4 months, without the
possibility of prosecution in a criminal court. The ‘hybrid’ model maintains the criminal offence, but
assumes that first-time offenders receive a fixed penalty and are not prosecuted, while repeat
offenders are prosecuted and can receive a variable fine up to a maximum of £1000. The model used
275
TV licence fee evasion is dealt with by TV Licensing, a registered brand name of the BBC. We refer to this
as the BBC for simplicity.
276
http://www.tvlicensing.co.uk/cs/media-centre/news/view.app?id=1362435051910.
277
http://www.bbc.co.uk/annualreport/2014/executive/finances/licence_fee.html.
278
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201314/ldhansrd/text/131128w0001.htm#wa_st_43.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
83
a baseline evasion rate of 5% (the current rate), so the results of their study should be viewed as
relative to this base.
The research was commissioned before the consultation was published, so the models used in the
research do not align entirely with the options described in the consultation document. Options 1 and
2 do not make significant changes to the current system, so are not expected to result in any
significant change in evasion. Options 3 and 4 do not align perfectly to the hybrid model in the
research, but there are enough similarities between the two options and the hybrid model to allow it to
be used as a proxy for these options.
279
Options 5 and 6 can both be equated to the ‘civil’ model.
Evasion rates under the ‘civil’ model are dependent on the fine level; for Option 5 this is uncertain, so
we have included both a £150 and a £500 penalty in the analysis. Option 6 is assumed to be the
equivalent of a £150 penalty under the civil model.
280
The table below sets out the six Review options alongside their associated Harris research model,
and the estimated potential change in evasion rates.
281
We have also estimated the potential change
in revenue to the BBC as a result of the projected change to evasion rates.
282
Option
Equivalent
Harris Option
Estimated Potential
Change in Evasion
Estimated Impact on Licence
Fee Revenue
1 Retain the
current system
Criminal
0%
0
2 Reform the
current system
n/a
0%
0
3 - Out-of-court
settlement
Hybrid
1% increase
-£39m
4 - Fixed Monetary
Penalty
Hybrid
1% increase
-£39m
5 Civil Monetary
Penalty
Civil (£150/£500
fine)
3.9%/0.4% increase
-£156m/-£16m
6 Civil Debt
Civil with £150
fine
3.9% increase
-£156m
Option 1. Retain the current criminal enforcement system
Under the current system, the case is prosecuted by the BBC (as TV Licensing) after the BBC has
investigated the defendant privately (which attracts its own costs). The case is then heard with other
similar cases in a Magistrates' Court (around 15% of cases are withdrawn
283
), which has a time and
279
More information can be found in the Option 3 and Option 4 sections below.
280
This conclusion is explained in more detail in the Option 6 section below.
281
It should be noted that in the Harris Interactive research and report, the term ‘fine’ is used in a general
sense, and that therefore throughout this document the term ‘fine’ appears in relation to Harris research where it
may in fact refer to another type of penalty, such as a civil debt or out of court settlement.
282
BBC evidence submitted to the Review. Each 1% rise in evasion rate would amount to £39m in lost revenue
for the BBC.
283
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201314/ldhansrd/text/131128w0001.htm#wa_st_43.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
84
cost implication for the court. However, despite the large number of cases, they are dealt with
efficiently and take up only 0.3% of court time.
Of the defendants found guilty, around 99.5% are fined.
284
Her Majesty’s Courts and Tribunals
Service (HMCTS) incurs the cost of enforcing the fine, but also collects the fine revenue. Not all fines
are successfully enforced, so although HMCTS will incur enforcement costs for all cases, it receives
fine revenue from only a portion of cases, some of which is paid into the Consolidated Fund.
285
The BBC is able to apply for a refund of its enforcement costs, which are added to the amount the
defendant has to pay (though as these are not always recovered, the BBC does not recover its full
costs). In the BBC consultation response it is noted that the BBC was awarded £13.1m in costs
2012/13, but only received £9.5m: a recovery rate of 73%.
286
It also suggests that the average cost
order made during that period was around £87.
287
As well as costs and the fine, the financial penalty will generally include a victim surcharge (a
minimum of £20) and the recently introduced criminal courts charge
288
of around £150 (for those who
plead guilty; proceeding to trial will incur a higher cost
289
). This cost will be repaid to the court and
(unlike the fine element of the penalty) is not subject to means-testing.
In the consultation document we estimated the average cost of a case to the court system. A key part
of this model was the cost of sitting in a Magistrates’ Court per day, from which we could estimate the
average cost of a case. This model assumed that the time taken to hear a licence fee case in court
would be equivalent to that of the average Magistrates’ Court case. The BBC stated in its consultation
response that this was an over-estimate as the average licence fee evasion case is much faster to
process than the average of all cases, particularly as many licence fee cases are dealt with in bulk
and are uncontested. We have taken this view into account and have produced an amended ‘cost to
the court’ figure. This is based on the consultation response from the Ministry of Justice, which
provides a more robust figure of £28 per case.
The defendant is not required to pay any backdated, outstanding licence fee as part of the punitive
measure, thus the BBC does not recoup lost licence fee revenue.
Costs to the Government
Court costs: The Ministry of Justice has calculated the average cost of hearing TV licence
fee evasion cases at approximately £28 per case. This is likely to be an over-estimate (as it
includes assessment of some more complex cases) and the cost is likely to fall as a result of
planned efficiencies.
290
To find the cost to the Magistrates' Courts of enforcing fines we used
the total cost of enforcement in a year and the number of cases being enforced to find a per-
284
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201314/ldhansrd/text/131128w0001.htm#wa_st_43 .
285
The Consolidated Fund is a fund into which all public revenue is paid and which provides the supply for all
public services. The basis of the financial mechanism by which the Consolidated Fund is operated is governed
by the Exchequer and Audit Departments Act 1866 and it is administered by the Treasury.
286
BBC consultation response.
287
£13.1m/150,000=£87.
288
Criminal Courts and Justice Act 2015. The charge will be levied against all offenders convicted of a criminal
offence on or after 13 April 2015.
289
Ministry of Justice consultation response
290
The Ministry of Justice informed us that amendments to the system of summary justice by the Criminal
Justice and Courts Act 2015 are likely to lower the costs of cases including those involving TV licence fee
evasion. The Ministry of Justice also notes that future automation of many of the (currently manual)
administrative processes carried out by the courts will lower the cost of fine enforcement and increase the
amount collected by way of fines.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
85
case-per-year cost.
291
We then factored in the average time taken to enforce the fine, which
gave an average cost of enforcement per case: £59.
292
Summing the two (cost of a case plus
cost of enforcement) gives the total average cost of a case to the court system of £87. Thus
we estimate that TV licence enforcement costs the court system £13m a year (based on
150,000 cases).
Imprisonment: in 2013/14 32 individuals were imprisoned for defaulting on fines imposed for
TV licence fee evasion. The average period of committal was approximately 3 weeks, which
the Ministry of Justice has estimated cost Her Majesty’s Prison Service (HMPS) approximately
£22,000, or £100 per prisoner per day.
293
Benefits to the Government
Fine revenue: 99.5%
294
of those prosecuted are issued a fine. In 2013 the average fine was
£169.37.
295
The revenue from this is shared between the courts and the Government.
However not all of the fine revenue imposed by the courts is fully recovered. As this depends
on a great many factors it is difficult to quantify, but we can use the BBC’s cost recovery rate
(73%) as a proxy. We could therefore estimate £25.3m
296
as the amount of fine revenue
received.
Criminal courts charge: as this is a new charge it is difficult to say how collection will
operate, but we could estimate this at around £16.4m in revenue.
297
This calculation uses the
BBC’s 73% fine repayment as a proxy in order to provide a quantitative estimate, however as
we do not have any data on the payment rate, this may be an over-estimate as it will be the
last monetary charge collected. Additionally some defendants will opt for a trial and face a
higher charge, but that figure is uncertain so has been excluded for simplicity.
Costs to the BBC
Investigation and prosecution: the BBC will incur costs for investigation and prosecution,
which vary according to each case. The BBC spends 2.7% of the licence fee on licence
enforcement; in 2013-14, this was £102m.
298
Benefits to the BBC
Costs awarded: the BBC applies for a refund of its prosecution costs, which is granted by the
court in a portion of cases, but not always recovered. The cost of prosecution to the BBC in
291
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/323112/hmcts-annual-report-
2013-14.PDF
292
Information on the enforcement costs of all Magistrates’ Court fines was provided to the Review by the
Ministry of Justice. Cost of enforcement per year (47.1m) / no. of cases heard (1.2m) * time taken to enforce
(1.5 years) = £59
293
Based on average annual cost per prison place of £25,000, and an average sentence served of 52%.
(3/52*£25,000*52%*32 = £22,000) Ministry of Justice response to the consultation.
294
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201314/ldhansrd/text/131128w0001.htm#wa_st_43
295
https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/criminal-court-statistics-quarterly-july-to-september-2014
296
(150,000 * 99.5% * £169.37) = £25.3m
297
At £150, with 150,000 cases a year, and assuming again a 73% collection rate, this can be estimated at
£16.4m.
298
http://downloads.bbc.co.uk/annualreport/pdf/2013-14/BBC_Financial_statements_201314.pdf.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
86
England and Wales is around £120 per case. In 2012/13, it was awarded £13.1m in costs by
the courts (around £87 per case). Of this, it actually received £9.5m: £63 per case.
299
Costs to the individual
Fine: as noted above, the average fine issued in 2013/14 was £169.37.
Costs: individuals found guilty can be issued costs on top of the fine amount, including
prosecution costs (~£87), the victim surcharge (~£20) and the new criminal courts charge
(£150). Thus we can estimate court costs of around £247.
Time: the individual will also face personal costs for attending court, such as travel and loss of
income.
Affected Group
Costs
Benefits
Government
Court costs - £13m per annum (pa)
Imprisonment - £22,000 pa
Fine revenue - £25.3m pa
Criminal courts charge - £16.4m pa
BBC
Investigation and prosecution -
£102m pa
Court costs returned - £9.5m pa
Individual
Fine - £169.37
Court costs (~£247)
Travel and loss of income.
This cost-benefit table will act as the counterfactual against which all of the other options will be
measured. Similar tables for the remaining options will indicate whether the costs and benefits are
higher or lower than this counterfactual (and include any new costs/benefits).
Option 2. Reform of the current system: leave the current offence as it stands, but reform the
current criminal enforcement system
Option 2 would not make substantive changes to the process of enforcement; this option would
involve retaining the current criminal offence while at the same time making improvements to the
system of enforcement so as to address some of the concerns that gave rise to the Review.
The Review makes a number of recommendations which are discussed in the text of the main report.
However, only one of the recommendations has potentially significant cost implications.
Recommendation 6:
TV Licensing should consider increasing the transparency of its prosecution and enforcement policy,
and provide clearer guidance to those at risk of prosecution. This guidance could take the form of a
code detailing the steps that will be taken before prosecution, including the public interest
considerations that will be applied when deciding whether to prosecute. Any such code should be
published and made available to suspected evaders at the earliest possible opportunity in the
enforcement process.
299
BBC consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
87
Evidence gathered during the review has demonstrated that there are opportunities to divert evaders
from prosecution throughout the existing enforcement process. The current system affords evaders
more flexibility than is perhaps generally acknowledged. By improving public knowledge of these
opportunities to avoid prosecution, there could potentially be an increase in at least the number of
delayers, and potentially also the number of evaders. Any rise in the evasion rate would be troubling
for the BBC as each additional 1% rise in evasion is estimated to cost the BBC £39m. However, as the
report concludes, given that the threat of prosecution remains, and any deliberate attempt to exploit the
policy would be a factor in favour of prosecution, it seems unlikely that evasion will increase. This is
particularly so given that a policy of encouraging compliance rather than resorting to prosecution is
already in operation, and the only difference is that it will be publicised.
Some of the changes outlined in the other recommendations could also have an impact on the costs
of the BBC, for example any work done to alter the tone and content of it written communications with
households could potentially increase the BBC’s administration and investigation costs. However the
other changes outlined for this option are not substantive enough, and do not affect key variables
(such as method of enforcement) enough to significantly affect the cost-benefit analysis.
Option 3. Out-of-court settlement: retain the criminal offence, with an option for disposal by
way of an out-of-court settlement.
This option would offer evaders the opportunity to avoid prosecution by paying the BBC an agreed
amount as an out-of-court settlement. If the individual decided not to take up the settlement, the case
would be pursued through the Magistrates’ Court in the usual manner.
There is uncertainty over the proportion of individuals likely to accept an out-of-court settlement, and
this would have a significant bearing on the eventual costs. The level of the settlement would need to
be set at a level high enough to deter evasion (that is, higher than the cost of a TV licence) and to
cover the running costs of the scheme, but low enough to encourage individuals to take up the offer.
This would suggest a figure between £145.50 (the current licence fee) and lower than £169.37 (the
current average fine).
However, as a comparative example, in most parking and waiting offence cases the maximum level
of penalty is £60-£90.
300
A figure this low carries the risk of increasing evasion, as it is lower than the
cost of a TV licence.
If the individual chose not to accept the settlement, they would be prosecuted in the Magistrates’
Court as under the current system. Therefore this Option would seem to provide greater value for
money for the taxpayer, as there would be fewer cases proceeding to the Magistrates’ Court for
prosecution. However it is hard to say what percentage of individuals this will be, and comparisons
with similar systems in use are difficult as data is fragmented. Significantly, the Ministry of Justice
believes that although there could be a cost saving by using a system of out-of-court settlement, the
saving would be limited (on the basis that the existing system is efficient and does not impose a
significant burden on the taxpayer in terms of cost) and would depend on evasion remaining at the
current level. It also noted that the court would no longer receive fine revenue and whether or not it
would result in a saving to the taxpayer would depend on a number of factors (the acceptance rate,
enforcement costs and level of the penalty).
301
300
In the case of parking related PCNs, the offence is halved if paid within 14 days.
http://www.theaa.com/motoring_advice/legal-advice/penalty-charge-notice.html.
301
Ministry of Justice evidence-gathering session.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
88
Another concern raised about an out-of-court settlement scheme is the potential rise in delayed
paying, as any additional unlicensed time is a further loss of revenue for the BBC. The option to agree
an out-of-court settlement before criminal action is taken could provide an incentive for individuals to
delay buying a licence until they are threatened with legal action, particularly if the level of the
settlement was lower than that of the licence fee (as is the case in Scotland).
Scotland
The Scottish Government uses an out-of-court settlement scheme for TV licence evasion. The
average fiscal fine issued for TV licence fee evasion in Scotland is £75
302
, within the £60-£90 band
mentioned above for parking offences, but below the TV licence fee of £145.50. Comparing the
evasion rates in Scotland and the rest of the UK before and after 2008 (when the fiscal fines system
in Scotland was strengthened
303
) provides some indication of the difference in evasion between an
alternative civil penalty method and a criminal method. However, direct comparison will be misleading
as there are fundamental differences between England and Wales and Scotland that will undermine
the value of any comparison.
304
The table below provides the evasion rates in Scotland as compared to the rest of the UK (roUK) from
2005 to 2014, along with a ratio of evasion in Scotland to the rest of the UK. The graph below shows
how evasion has changed over time, and how the relationship between evasion in Scotland and the
rest of the UK has evolved.
Evasion rate (%)
Year
Scotland
Rest of the UK
Ratio S/RoUK
2005
5.10
4.10
1.24
2006
4.90
4.01
1.22
2007
5.30
4.41
1.20
2008
5.50
4.47
1.23
2009
5.90
4.80
1.23
2010
5.90
4.82
1.22
2011
7.10
5.00
1.42
2012
7.80
5.36
1.46
2013
7.30
5.46
1.34
2014
7.30
5.16
1.42
It is important to note that although there was an increase in evasion in Scotland in 2011, this was
also the case for the rest of the UK.
It is not clear why there appears to be a jump in evasion rates in 2011 as there are no obvious
changes to policy which would lead to this. One possible contributing factor, along with a ratio of
302
Evidence provided by the Crown Office and Procurator Fiscal Service (COPFS): in 2013/14, 94% of cases
of TV licence fee evasion in Scotland resulted in a payment of £75 (12603 of the 13431).
303
BBC evidence to the Review: The Criminal Proceedings etc. (Reform) (Scotland) Act 2007 amended the
Criminal Procedure (Scotland) Act 1995 so that an offer of fiscal fine was deemed accepted if the alleged
offender failed to provide notice of refusal within 28 days of the offer. This change in legislation led to an
increase in the number of cases that received a fiscal fine and a reduction in the number of cases that were not
proceeded against. Prior to this an offer of fiscal fine that was not accepted required the Procurator Fiscal to
review the case for prosecution or other measures.
304
This is discussed in more detail in Chapter 3 of the report.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
89
evasion in Scotland to the rest of the UK. The graph below shows how evasion has changed over
time, and how the relationship between evasion in Scotland and the rest of the UK has evolved is
important to note that although there was
It is important to note that although there was an increase in evasion in Scotland in 2011, this was
also the case for the rest of the UK.
It is not clear why there appears to be a jump in evasion rates in 2011 as there are no obvious
changes to policy which would lead to this. One possible contributing factor could be the UK-wide
census in 2011, which led to a relatively significant re-estimation of population figures and therefore
could impact on any models which draw on population estimates.
Behavioural research and implications for evasion
The Harris Interactive research paper on behavioural changes did not specifically explore an out-of-
court settlement like that in Option 3, but the ‘hybrid’ model in the Harris Interactive research is similar
enough that we can use it as a proxy.
In the hybrid model, first-time offenders receive a monetary penalty while multiple offenders are
prosecuted through the criminal courts. This bears a similarity to an out-of-court settlement scheme,
wherein offenders who refuse or are not offered an out-of-court settlement would be prosecuted
through the Magistrates’ Court as under the current process.
The Harris Interactive hybrid model predicted that evasion would rise from the current rate of 5% to
6%. We therefore estimate that under Option 3 evasion would increase to 6%, costing the BBC an
extra £39m in lost revenue.
Costs to the Government
Court costs: The out-of-court settlement is designed to remove offenders from the court
system, so the cost to the Government will depend on the number of offenders who accept the
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
90
settlement and therefore do not proceed to prosecution. However as the court system deals
with TV licence fee evasion cases very efficiently, this potentially reduced number of cases
may not have a significant impact in terms of savings to the taxpayer.
Imprisonment: it is unclear whether this system would lead to an increase or decrease in the
numbers of individuals imprisoned, or the duration of imprisonment, and therefore the total
costs. We have therefore maintained the estimated cost from Option 1 of approximately
£22,000, or £100 per prisoner per day.
Benefits to the Government
Settlement revenue: the Government would receive the revenue from the settlements
issued. This would be calculated as the level of the penalty multiplied by the number of people
who pay it in order to avoid prosecution. As both these figures are uncertain, we have not
quantified this revenue.
Criminal courts charge: as cases which are diverted from the Magistrates’ Court will not
incur this charge, the Government would receive less revenue from this charge in accordance
with the number of cases diverted from prosecution.
Costs to the BBC
Set-up and administration: the BBC would have to invest in the establishment of an out-of-
court settlement scheme and bear the ongoing costs of administration, which may be
significant.
Evasion: the predicted increase in evasion from 5% to 6% would mean a loss of £39m in
licence fee revenue for the BBC.
Delayed payment: the number of people delaying purchase of a licence could increase under
this option, which means a further loss of revenue for the BBC for the unlicensed time.
Benefits to the BBC
Prosecution: the BBC bear the costs of prosecution if the case proceeds through the court
system, as in the current system of enforcement. However we expect that this would be lower
than under the current system as a number of offenders would avoid prosecution by paying a
settlement (though as this number is uncertain, we cannot estimate the cost impact). As with
the current system, the BBC would likely not recover all of its prosecution costs.
Settlement level: the BBC might benefit from the ability to set the level of the settlement. This
would mean that the BBC were able to raise the level of the settlement in order to cover the
increased costs of running the scheme (or the loss of revenue from increased evasion).
However if it were to rise above the level of the average fine (£169.37) it is unlikely that this
option would be used by defendants, and they would revert to the Magistrates’ Court (and the
costs/benefits outlined in Option 1).
Costs to the individual
Costs of proceeding to Magistrates’ Court: if the individual was not offered or did not
accept the settlement, the case would proceed to court, with the fine and costs as described in
Option 1.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
91
Benefits to the individual
Settlement: if the individual accepted the settlement, this would potentially be lower than the
average fine. As discussed above, it would be sensible to suggest a figure between £145.50
(the current licence fee) and £169.37 (the current average fine).
Court (and related) costs: those who accept an out-of-court settlement do not attend a
Magistrates’ Court and so do not pay court costs or lose any income.
Affected Group
Costs
Benefits
Government
Court costs likely lower than £13m
per annum (pa).
Imprisonment unknown. Assume
£22,000 pa.
Settlement revenue unknown,
dependent on level and
acceptance rate.
Criminal courts charge -
depends on acceptance rate,
likely lower.
BBC
Administration and set-up costs.
Likely increase in evasion - loss of
£39m licence fee revenue pa.
Potential loss of revenue through
increase in delayed payment.
Prosecution costs likely
lower as fewer cases in courts.
Court costs returned unknown
(dependent on the settlement
rate).
Flexibility to set level of
settlement.
Individual
Settlement: unknown, potentially
between £145.50 and £170.
Court costs (if settlement not accepted).
Travel and loss of income (if settlement
not accepted).
Court costs (£0 if settlement
accepted).
Travel and loss of income (£0 if
settlement accepted).
Option 4. Fixed monetary penalty: retain the criminal offence, with an option for disposal by
way of a fixed monetary penalty
Option 4 would retain TV licence evasion as a criminal offence, while allowing a fixed monetary
penalty to be imposed as a formal alternative to prosecution. This option is similar to Option 3 in that
the rationale for each is that they are intended to provide a swift and effective out-of-court disposal,
thus reducing the burden on the courts. However, unlike Option 3, Option 4 involves the possibility of
an out-of-court disposal by way of a fixed monetary penalty in every case of evasion, and the level of
the penalty is fixed.
Under Option 4 a penalty notice (or a notice of an intention to impose a fixed penalty) would be
issued by the authorised enforcement agency (TV Licensing) at the point at which an offence is
committed, for example, at the time a TV Licensing enquiry officer witnesses an offence on the
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
92
occasion of a household visit. In the event of default of payment the fixed penalty notice would be
enforced without resort to prosecution or, as an alternative, the case would proceed to the
Magistrates’ Court in the usual way.
Behavioural research and implications for evasion
The Harris Interactive research paper on behavioural changes did not specifically explore a fixed
monetary penalty scheme like that in Option 4, but the ‘hybrid’ model in the Harris research is similar
enough that we can use it as a proxy.
In the Harris hybrid model, first-time offenders receive a monetary penalty while multiple offenders
are prosecuted through the criminal courts. This bears a similarity to a fixed monetary penalty
scheme, wherein offenders who refuse to pay the fixed monetary penalty would be prosecuted
through the Magistrates’ Court as under the current process.
The Harris hybrid model predicted that evasion would rise from the current rate of 5% to 6%. We
therefore estimate that under Option 4 evasion would increase to 6%, costing the BBC an extra £39m
in lost revenue.
Costs to the Government
Court costs: the fixed monetary penalty scheme is designed to remove offenders from the
court system, so the cost to the Government will depend on the number of offenders who
accept the penalty and therefore do not proceed to prosecution. However as the court system
deals with TV licence fee evasion cases very efficiently, this potentially reduced number of
cases may not have a significant impact in terms of savings to the taxpayer.
o We can assume that the cost of this system will be the same as the current system:
~£87 per case. However the number of cases taken through the court process will
likely be less than in the current system: data from other civil claims made in this way
(for example a fixed monetary penalty) suggests around 65%
305
of individuals pay the
claim at the first stage. If we use this as a proxy, we can estimate that the full
Magistrates’ Court costs would only apply to the remaining 35%: a total cost of £4.6m.
However the court system takes on the burden of administration costs for the
remaining 65%. As discussed in Chapter 3 of the report, this would require significant
investment.
o Importantly, the behavioural research suggests that this Option would lead to a 1%
increase in evasion, which implies a rise in the number of cases (and subsequently
increased costs to the Government). However it is not possible to estimate this directly
as there are a number of uncertainties around its impact.
Imprisonment: it is unclear whether this system would lead to an increase or decrease in the
numbers of individuals imprisoned, or the duration of imprisonment, and therefore the total
costs. We have therefore maintained the estimated cost from Option 1 of approximately
£22,000, or £100 per prisoner per day.
305
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/115726/fixed-penalty-notice-
1011-tabs.xls. (2010)
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
93
Benefits to the Government
Penalty revenue: revenue from the penalty paid into the Consolidated Fund (the
Government’s general bank account). It is uncertain at this stage what the level of the penalty
would be, although, as noted in the main report analysis, it would need to be at a sufficient
level to provide a deterrent.
Criminal courts charge: this is fairly uncertain, but if we assume that 35% of cases proceed
to court, then we can estimate this as £5.7m.
306
Costs to the BBC
Set-up and administration: the BBC would have to invest in aspects of establishing the
scheme and administer its operation (for example, training enquiry officers to issue penalties),
which could be significant.
Enforcement: The BBC has stated that it would expect its collection costs to be higher using
this model than under the current system and noted that it is not clear that enforcement costs
would be recoverable through the fixed penalty process.
Evasion: the predicted increase in evasion from 5% to 6% would mean a loss of £39m in
licence fee revenue for the BBC.
Benefits to the BBC
Prosecution: the BBC bear the costs of prosecution if the case proceeds through the court
system, as in the current system of enforcement. However we expect that this would be lower
than under the current system as a number of offenders would avoid prosecution by paying a
settlement (though as this number is uncertain, we cannot estimate the cost impact). As with
the current system, the BBC would likely not recover all of its prosecution costs.
Costs to the individual
Costs of proceeding to Magistrates’ Court: if the individual refused to pay the penalty, the
case would proceed to court, with the fine and costs as described in Option 1.
Benefits to the individual
Penalty: if the individual accepted the penalty, this would potentially be lower than the
average fine. As discussed above, it would be sensible to suggest a figure between £145.50
(the current licence fee) and £169.37 (the current average fine).
Court (and related) costs: those who accept a fixed monetary penalty do not attend a
Magistrates’ Court and so do not pay court costs or lose any income.
306
If we assume that 35% of cases proceed to court, then the Government could receive the £150 charge in
(35% x 150,000) = 52,500 cases, which, with the previously assumed 73% collection rate, totals (£150 x 52,500
x 73%) = £5.7m. Note that the 73% is in relation to BBC fine revenue, so this is only a proxy.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
94
Affected Group
Costs
Benefits
Government
Court costs cost of hearing only 35%
of cases potentially reduced from
£13m to £4.6m pa (though could be
higher).
Administration unknown but
potentially significant costs of
administering the FPN for 65% of cases
Predicted 1% rise in evasion:
unknown additional costs
Imprisonment unknown. Assume
£22,000 pa
Penalty revenue unknown,
dependent on level and acceptance
rate.
Criminal courts charge - likely
reduced from £16.4m, potentially
to £5.7m.
BBC
Administration and set-up costs
Enforcement costs potentially
higher
Likely increase in evasion - loss of
£39m licence fee revenue.
Prosecution costs potentially
lower as fewer cases in the
Magistrates’ Court.
Individual
Penalty unknown, potentially between
£145.50 and £170
Court costs (if penalty not accepted).
Travel and loss of income (if penalty not
accepted).
Court costs (£0 if penalty accepted).
Travel and loss of income (£0 if
penalty accepted).
Option 5. Civil monetary penalty: decriminalise and enforce via a civil infraction
Option 5 involves the repeal of the TV licence fee offence, the creation of a statutory obligation to
have a TV licence and enforcement of this obligation through the imposition of a civil monetary
penalty. A civil monetary penalty is neither a fine nor a criminal conviction: it is instead a penalty for
failing to comply with a statutory obligation. The scale of the penalty would be crucial: it would have
to be set at a level high enough to deter evasion, while at the same time low enough to encourage
acceptance at an early stage of the enforcement process. Treating the licence fee as a civil debt
would provide some savings to the taxpayer, who would not be required to meet the costs of the civil
proceedings. On the other hand, the cost to the licence fee payer is likely to increase significantly, for
reasons explained below.
Under Option 5, if the penalty remained unpaid it would be treated as a civil debt. The civil claimant
(the BBC) would be responsible for pursuing the claim, and therefore the BBC would be liable for all
costs, including enforcement of the civil penalty; it can seek to recover its costs, but these come
directly from the individual, not from the courts. The high cost of enforcement means there is an
added risk for the BBC in pursuing the case beyond the first claim stage. The percentage of
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
95
individuals who pay after the first claim is important as it has an impact on the overall costs and
benefits to all parties, but particularly for the BBC.
An individual would have the opportunity to make an informal challenge to the notice and if
unsuccessful, the individual would have a right of appeal and it is envisaged that this appeal would be
to an independent adjudicator. Enforcement of the penalty would take place in the civil court system
and thus would involve conventional methods of enforcement, such as the employment of bailiffs,
seizure of property, and the use of attachment of earnings and charging orders.
The crucial point here is that the BBC would have to make a judgment about whether to continue to
pursue individual cases: as it is responsible for all costs there would be a greater focus on the point at
which the cost of the enforcement process outweighs the benefit (the likelihood of successfully
enforcing the penalty).
There could also be a change in long-term behavioural patterns associated with this option as a result
of increased risk for the BBC and decreased risk for the consumer.
Behavioural research and implications for evasion
The Harris research’s ‘civil’ model is comparable to this option, thus we could use the results from the
Harris research to inform our estimates of any changes in evasion from this option. Crucially, the
research showed that evasion under this model is determined mainly by the fine
307
or penalty level. At
a penalty level of £150 evasion is projected to increase to 8.9%, costing the BBC £156m a year in lost
revenue. With a fine of £500 however, evasion increases only to 5.4% (compared with the 5%
baseline in the model), a loss of £16m revenue. However it should be noted that a £500 penalty is
significantly higher than the current average fine (£170).
Responsibility for licence fee evasion cases would be transferred from the criminal court system to
the civil courts. The civil courts have existing frameworks for dealing with similar types of money
claims, so this could be dealt with efficiently. There will be costs to the BBC for each case, and higher
costs for those where the penalty was not paid and which had to be pursued through the courts as a
civil debt. This cost would be significant as the BBC would need to fund all methods of enforcement of
the debt.
Costs to the Government
Set-up and administration: there will be a cost associated with either setting up or using an
existing appeals process, which would fall to either the Government or the BBC.
Criminal court charge: if the offence was decriminalised the criminal courts charge would not
apply, representing an estimated (see above) loss of revenue of £16.4m.
Benefits to the Government
Criminal court efficiency: removing TV licence fee evasion cases from the Magistrates’
Court would improve efficiency, although to a very minor extent (0.3%) as they are dealt with
very efficiently under the current system.
307
It should be noted that in the Harris Interactive research and report, the term ‘fine’ is used in a general sense
to refer to both criminal and civil monetary penalties. We have chosen to refer to this as a penalty, for
consistency with the report. The current maximum fine is £1000, while the average fine is around £170.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
96
Civil court costs: although the civil courts would face greater case numbers, the BBC would
be responsible for the court fees (recoverable from the individual) and the Ministry of Justice
believes that the cost of enforcing civil penalties is fully recovered by HMCTS.
308
Costs to the BBC
Collection costs: the costs involved in collecting the licence fee are likely to increase.
309
Set-up and administration: the costs of administering the penalty scheme would likely fall to
the BBC.
Court costs: in the event of non-payment the BBC is responsible for all costs related to
pursuing the debt, as well as costs of enforcement. Some would be recovered through penalty
revenue and civil debts successfully enforced, but we anticipate that this would be a
significant burden for the BBC.
Evasion: the Harris model predicts that under a civil model evasion will increase. At a penalty
level of £150 evasion is predicted to increase to 8.9%, which would cost the BBC around
£156m a year in lost revenue. Where the penalty level was £500, evasion was predicted to
increase to 5.4%, which would cost the BBC around £16m a year in lost revenue.
Cost-benefit ratio: the increased pressure on the BBC raises concerns about the commercial
benefit of pursuing certain cases, with the result that a certain level of evasion might be
tolerated or written off, on the grounds that enforcement is simply not cost-effective.
Set-up and administration of appeals body: there will be a cost associated with either
setting up or using an existing appeals process, which would fall to either the Government or
the BBC.
Benefits to the BBC
Penalty revenue: the BBC will receive the revenue from the penalty, however this depends
on the level of the penalty and the number of cases diverted from the courts by the penalty.
Civil debt repayment: the BBC will also receive the revenue of those cases which it
successfully pursues (including court costs).
Costs to the individual
Costs of proceeding to civil court: if the individual refused to pay the penalty, the case
would proceed to the civil court, with a potential civil debt and costs to pay.
Benefits to the individual
Penalty: if the individual accepted the penalty, this would potentially be lower than the civil
debt they would receive if the case moved to a civil court.
Court (and related) costs: those who accept the penalty do not attend a civil court and so do
not pay court costs or lose any income.
308
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
309
BBC and Ministry of Justice evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
97
Affected Group
Costs
Benefits
Government
Criminal courts charge loss of £16.4m
pa.
Potential cost for set-up/ administration
of appeals body.
Court costs reduced from
£13m to £0.
Imprisonment reduced from
£22,000 to £0.
BBC
Collection costs likely increase
Administration and set-up costs
(scheme and potentially appeals body)
Court costs likely significant increase
Likely increase in evasion - loss of up to
£156m licence fee revenue pa.
Penalty and civil debt revenue -
unknown
Individual
Penalty unknown, potentially between
£145.50 and £170
Court costs (if penalty not accepted).
Travel and loss of income (if penalty not
accepted).
Court costs (£0 if penalty
accepted).
Travel and loss of income (£0 if
penalty accepted).
Option 6. Civil debt: decriminalise and enforce as a civil debt
Option 6 would involve treating the licence fee as a civil debt recoverable through the civil courts. This
is currently the position in the case of non-payment of utility bills, where, as a matter of last resort, the
debtor may be proceeded against in the County Court where, if liability is proved, an order may be
obtained requiring payment of the debt. The exact legal structure of this option would have an impact
on the cost-benefit analysis.
310
It is likely that under such an option the BBC would be responsible for pursuing the debt through the
civil courts. In this way it is similar to Option 5 (without the initial civil monetary penalty offer), in that
the burden of cost is mainly with the BBC, and there is an inherent risk of not receiving revenue
should enforcement fail.
This option broadly aligns with the Harris Interactive behavioural research ‘civil’ model, although it is
hard to provide any estimate for the level of civil debt as this would likely involve an assumption as to
the period of unlicensed use.
311
Nevertheless, for the purposes of this analysis we have used £150 as
a suggested model (being the level of the civil penalty in the Harris civil model and broadly similar to
the cost of an annual TV licence). Using that figure we could therefore assume that the rise in evasion
310
For example, if it were treated as a priority debt, the use of imprisonment as an ultimate sanction for non-
payment would still be available.
311
One of the key difficulties inherent in Option 6 is that in order to enforce a civil debt, the BBC would have to
provide evidence of the period of time for which the individual had been unlicensed and the amount of the debt
would be in a sum corresponding to the period of evasion. It would be difficult to prove the period of unlicensed
use with the result that the amount of the debt is likely to be small or nominal.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
98
observed in the Harris model would apply for Option 6: an increase to 8.9%, which would cost the
BBC an additional £156m in lost revenue per year.
The table below represents the potential costs and benefits under a non-statutory system. If the debt
were treated as a priority debt, there would be other costs associated with sentencing and
imprisonment.
Costs to the Government
Criminal court charge: if the offence was decriminalised the criminal courts charge would not
apply, representing an estimated (see above) loss of revenue of £16.4m.
Benefits to the Government
Criminal court efficiency: removing TV licence fee evasion cases from the Magistrates
Court would improve efficiency, although to a very minor extent (0.3%) as they are dealt with
very efficiently under the current system.
Civil court costs: although the civil courts would face greater case numbers, the BBC would
be responsible for the court fees (recoverable from the individual) and the Ministry of Justice
believes that the cost of enforcing civil penalties is fully recovered by HMCTS.
312
Costs to the BBC
Collection costs: the costs involved in collecting the licence fee are likely to increase.
313
Court costs: the BBC would be responsible for all costs related to pursuing the debt, as well
as costs of enforcement. Some would be recovered through penalty revenue and civil debts
successfully enforced, but we anticipate that this would be a significant burden for the BBC.
Evasion: the Harris model predicts that under a civil model evasion will increase, at a penalty
level of £150 evasion is predicted to increase to 8.9%, which would cost the BBC around
£156m a year in lost revenue.
Cost-benefit ratio: the increased pressure on the BBC raises concerns about the commercial
benefit of pursuing certain cases, with the result that a certain level of evasion might be
tolerated or written off, on the grounds that enforcement is simply not cost-effective.
Benefits to the BBC
Penalty revenue: the BBC will receive the revenue from the penalty, however this depends
on the level of the penalty and the number of cases diverted from the courts by the penalty.
Civil debt repayment: the BBC will also receive the revenue of those cases which it
successfully pursues (including court costs).
312
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
313
BBC and Ministry of Justice evidence to the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
99
Costs to the individual
Costs of proceeding to civil court: if the individual refused to pay the penalty, the case
would proceed to the civil court, with a potential civil debt and costs to pay. This figure is
unknown.
Benefits to the individual
Court (and related) costs: those who accept the penalty do not attend a civil court and so do
not pay court costs or lose any income.
Affected Group
Costs
Benefits
Government
Criminal courts charge loss of £16.4m pa.
Court costs reduced from
£13m to £0.
Imprisonment reduced from
£22,000 to £0.
BBC
Collection costs likely increase
Administration and set-up costs
Court costs likely significant increase
Likely increase in evasion - loss of up to
£156m licence fee revenue pa.
Penalty and civil debt revenue
- unknown
Individual
Penalty unknown
Court costs (if penalty not accepted).
Travel and loss of income (if penalty not
accepted).
Court costs (£0 if penalty
accepted).
Travel and loss of income (£0
if penalty accepted).
Risks and Assumptions
In calculating the costs and benefits, we have (for the purposes of simplicity) not accounted for wider
factors which we believe would have a negligible impact (for example, inflation, population growth,
technological change). We have also assumed that a number of variables (such as court
administration costs and wages) will remain constant.
The analysis was informed by data from England and Wales, and has not gone into detail on the
jurisdictional differences in the devolved administrations and Crown Dependencies (with the
exception of the Scottish out-of-court settlement system discussed in Option 3), in order to focus the
analysis and make comparison between the options more clear. Further details on the jurisdictional
differences in enforcement can be found at Annex C, and relevant evidence is discussed in Chapter 3
of the report.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
100
This analysis relies in part on the behavioural research study carried out by Harris Interactive, which
informed a portion of the cost-benefit analysis for most options. This research was commissioned by
the BBC, however, as we explain in Annex E, the Review team scrutinised the work and carried out
quality assurance, concluding that the research a reliable source.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
101
ANNEX C: JURISDICTIONAL DIFFERENCES
England &
Wales
Scotland
Northern
Ireland
Jersey
Guernsey
Isle of Man
Investigat
ing
authority
TV Licensing
TV Licensing
who pass
information
to Procurator
Fiscal who
decides
whether or
not to
prosecute.
TV Licensing
TV Licensing
pass
information
onto police
who conduct
their own
investigation.
TV Licensing
pass cases
to an
Inspector in
the
Guernsey
prosecution
unit.
Evidence
reviewed by
law officers.
TV Licensing
Prosecuti
ng
authority
TV Licensing
Procurator
Fiscal
TV Licensing
Centenier
Police and
law officers
The Manx
Advocate
Relevant
Legislatio
n
Communicati
ons Act 2003
Communicati
ons Act 2003
Communicati
ons Act 2003
Broadcasting
&
Communicati
ons (Jersey)
Order 2004
Communicati
ons
(Bailiwick of
Guernsey)
Order 2004
Communicati
ons (Isle of
Man) Order
2003
Maximum
fine level
£1000
£1000
£1000
£500
£2000
£1000
Case
heard
by?
Magistrates
court
Sheriffs
Court
District judge
Magistrates
court
Magistrates
Court
Magistrates
Court
Can the
BBC
recover
costs?
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Yes
Can the
offence
be
disposed
of outside
of court?
No
Yes
No
No
No
No
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
102
ANNEX D: SUMMARY OF THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK
TV Licensing (England and Wales)
1. The statutory framework for the licensing of TV reception is set out in Part 4 of the
Communications Act 2003. Section 363 of this Part provides as follows:
Section 363 Licence required for use of TV receiver
(1) A television receiver must not be installed or used unless the installation and use of the
receiver is authorised by a licence under this Part.
(2) A person who installs or uses a television receiver in contravention of subsection (1) is
guilty of an offence.
(3) A person with a television receiver in his possession or under his control who
(a) intends to install or use it in contravention of subsection (1), or
(b) knows, or has reasonable grounds for believing, that another person intends to
install or use it in contravention of that subsection, is guilty of an offence.
(4) A person guilty of an offence under this section shall be liable, on summary conviction, to
a fine not exceeding level 3 on the standard scale.
(5) Subsection (1) is not contravened by anything done in the course of the business of a
dealer in television receivers solely for one or more of the following purposes
(a) installing a television receiver on delivery;
(b) demonstrating, testing or repairing a television receiver.
(6) The Secretary of State may by regulations exempt from the requirement of a licence under
subsection (1) the installation or use of television receivers
(a) of such descriptions,
(b) by such persons,
(c) in such circumstances, and (d) for such purposes, as may be provided for in the
regulations.
(7) Regulations under subsection (6) may make any exemption for which such regulations
provide subject to compliance with such conditions as may be specified in the regulations.
2. A television receiver must not be installed or used unless the installation and use of the receiver
is authorised by a licence under Part 4 (a ‘TV Licence’).
314
The definition of a television receiver
is set out in the Communication (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004
315
and means any
apparatus installed or used for the purpose of receiving (whether by means of wireless
telegraphy or otherwise) any television programme service, whether or not it is installed or used
for any other purpose.
314
Section 363(1) of the Communications Act 2003.
315
S.I. 2004/692 (as amended by S.I. 2005/606, S.I. 2006/619, S.I. 2007/718, S.I. 2008/643 and S.I. 2009/505
an S.I. 2010/640).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
103
3. References to using a television receiver are references to using it to receive television
programmes.
316
The reference to receiving a television programme service includes a reference
to receiving by any means any programme included in that service, where that programme is
received at the same time (or virtually the same time) as it is received by members of the public
by virtue of its being broadcast or distributed as part of that service.
317
4. This means a person needs to be authorised by a TV licence to watch or record TV as it is being
broadcast or otherwise distributed. This includes the use of devices such as a computer, laptop,
mobile phone or digital/personal video recorder.
5. TV licences are issued by the BBC.
318
A person to whom a TV licence is issued is liable to pay
a sum as provided for in the 2004 Regulations (the TV licence fee’).
319
The current fee for a
‘colour’ licence is £145.50.
320
The 2004 Regulations also set out the entitlement for concessions
and payment by instalments. The TV licence fee must be paid to the BBC and is recoverable
by them. The sums received by the BBC must be paid into the Consolidated Fund.
321
6. A person who installs or uses a television receiver without the installation or use being
authorised by a TV licence is guilty of an offence. A person found guilty of an offence is liable
to a fine not exceeding level 3 on the standard scale (£1000). The offence is dealt with by the
Magistrates Court.
322
Enforcement
7. ‘TV Licensing’ is a trademark of the BBC and is used under licence by companies contracted
by the BBC to administer the collection of the TV licence fee and enforcement of the TV
Licensing system. Capita Business Services Ltd is contracted in relation to the administration
and enforcement of the TV licence fee. The BBC retains overall responsibility.
8. The investigation into whether a person has committed a TV Licensing offence is carried out by
TV Licensing. Enquiry officers do not need any specific legal powers to carry out their
investigation: in particular, they do not have any police powers. They do however comply with
a code of conduct, visiting guidelines and, when conducting interviews, have regard to the
Police and Criminal Evidence Act 1984 (PACE) Codes of Practice. That is, enquiry officers will
give a caution to person concerned - if there are grounds to suspect an offence has been
committed before interviewing a suspect enquiry officers will caution the person concerned by
informing them that they do not have to say anything, but it may harm their defence if they do
316
Section 368(3).
317
Regulation 9 of the Communication (Television Licensing) Regulations 2004.
318
Section 364.
319
Section 365.
320
Schedule 1 to the 2004 Regulations.
321
Section 365. The BBC receives grant in aid from DCMS equal to the revenue from the TV licence fee (less
the department’s expenses in administering the licensing system - see clause 75 of the BBC Framework
Agreement of 30 June 2006).
322
Section 363.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
104
not mention when questioned something which they later rely on in court and that anything they
do say may be given in evidence.
9. A court may grant a warrant to enter and search a premises if the court is satisfied that there
are reasonable grounds for believing that an offence under section 363 of the Communications
Act 2003 is being committed and that evidence of the commission of the offence is likely to be
on the premises. This is subject to one of the following conditions being met: (a) there is no
person entitled to grant entry to the premises with whom it is practicable to communicate; (b)
there is no person entitled to grant access to the evidence with whom it is practicable to
communicate; (c) entry to the premises will not be granted unless a warrant is produced; or (d)
the purpose of the search may be frustrated or seriously prejudiced unless the search is carried
out by a person who secures entry immediately upon arriving at the premises. The person is
authorised to examine or test any television received found on the premises.
323
10. The person authorised
324
to enter and search the premises may (if necessary) use such force
as may be reasonable to do so. TV Licensing’s policy is not to use force and to exercise search
warrants in the presence of police officers whenever possible. Police officers may force entry if
they deem it necessary.
11. A person who intentionally obstructs a person in the exercise of any power granted by a warrant
is guilty of an offence and liable to a fine not exceeding level 5 on the standard scale
325
.
Prosecution
12. Prosecutions are brought by TV Licensing (a private prosecution). In deciding whether or not to
bring a prosecution TV Licensing adopt the approach in the Code for Crown Prosecutors:
326
TV
Licensing must be satisfied that there is sufficient evidence to provide a realistic prospect of
conviction (the evidential test); and, where the evidential test is satisfied, TV Licensing must go
on to consider whether a prosecution is required in the public interest (the public interest test).
Sentencing
13. A Magistrates Court must have regard to the Magistrates’ Court Sentencing Guidelines
327
when
assessing the fine to be imposed when a person has been convicted of a TV Licensing
offence.
328
The amount of the fine must reflect the seriousness of the offence and the court must
take into account the financial circumstances of the offender; this applies whether it has the
effect of increasing or reducing the fine. Normally a fine should be of an amount that is capable
323
Section 366.
324
Only a person so authorised by the BBC or Ofcom can exercise the warrant power (s.366(5) of the
Communications Act 2003)
325
As a result of s.85 of the Legal Aid, Sentencing and Punishment of Offenders Act 2012 being commenced
on 12 March, level 5 fines are now ‘unlimited’.
326
https://www.cps.gov.uk/publications/code_for_crown_prosecutors/codetest.html
327
https://www.sentencingcouncil.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/MCSG_web_-_October_2014.pdf
328
Section 125 of the Coroners and Justice Act 2009.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
105
of being paid within 12 months. The aim is for the fine to have an equal impact on offenders
with different financial circumstances; it should be a hardship but should not force the offender
below a reasonable ‘subsistence’ level.
14. The court will identify an appropriate starting point. For example, the starting point for up to six
months unlicensed use is a Band A fine (50% of relevant weekly income with a range of 25%
to 75% of relevant weekly income) and over 6 months of unlicensed use a Band B fine (100%
of relevant weekly income with a range of 25% to 125%).
15. The court will consider other aggravating factors (e.g. previous convictions) and mitigating
factors. In particular, the following factors indicate lower culpability: accidental oversight or belief
licence held, confusion of responsibility, licence immediately obtained. The court will consider
offender mitigation (e.g. genuine remorse, cooperation) and a reduction for a guilty plea.
16. The court will decide the sentence and give reasons.
Enforcement of a fine
17. The procedure for the enforcement of fines is set out in sections 75 to 91 of the Magistrates
Court Act 1980 and the Courts Act 2003. The enforcement of fines is complex, so what follows
can be considered to be a summary of the general process.
18. A court may allow time for payment of a fine or payment by instalments instead of requiring
immediate payment. The court will make a collection order with the details about how the fine
should be paid. If a person fails to pay the fine (or instalment) in the time allowed by the court,
the court can issue a summons or warrant for the person to appear before the court in order to
conduct a means inquiry to investigate the person’s ability to pay.
19. As a result of the information received at the means inquiry the court has a number of options:
the court may grant further time to pay the fine; change the instalment plan; remit some or all of
the fine having regard to any change in the person’s circumstances since conviction.
20. The court may only order imprisonment following such a means inquiry if it is satisfied that the
failure to pay the fine is due to wilful refusal or culpable neglect. ‘Wilful refusal’ means a
deliberate defiance of the court order and ‘culpable neglect’ means a reckless disregard of the
court order. This must be established beyond reasonable doubt.
21. The court must have also considered or tried all other methods of enforcing payment (e.g.
money payment supervision order, application for deduction from benefit, attachment of
earnings order) and concluded that they are inappropriate or unsuccessful. The warrant of
commitment (i.e. imprisonment) must state the grounds on which the court was satisfied that it
was undesirable or impracticable to use the other methods of enforcement.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
106
Consequences of a conviction
22. The offence of installing or using a television receiver without a TV licence (section 363 of the
Communications Act 2030) is not a recordable offence.
329
A conviction of this offence is unlikely
to be recorded on the Police National Computer unless it was dealt with at the same time as a
recordable offence.
23. A person is therefore not required to disclose such a conviction if asked to disclose convictions
for recordable offences in any job or other application (e.g. insurance). A person is required to
disclose such a conviction if asked to disclose all criminal convictions unless the conviction is
spent.
330
The rehabilitation period (i.e. the period after which the conviction is spent) for a
conviction sentenced with a fine is 12 months from the date of conviction.
331
329
National Police Records (Recordable Offences) Regulations 2000.
330
There are exceptions - spent convictions must be disclosed in relation to particularly sensitive areas such as
work with children and vulnerable adults, work in law enforcement and the legal system.
331
Section 5 of the Rehabilitation of Offenders Act 1975 (as amended).
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
107
ANNEX E: ANALYSIS OF KEY EVIDENCE
Literature Review
1. There is no pre-existing evidence which is directly comparable to the issue of decriminalisation
of TV licence evasion, however there is some literature which provides evidence on the
relationship between law formulation and other crime rates, or crime rates in general. An
internal review of this literature
332
suggests that the formulation of the law itself does not have
a deterrent effect in itself. Rather, it suggests that it is the methods of enforcement, and
likelihood of being caught, that have discernible deterrent effects.
2. These findings would suggest that the biggest behavioural changes seen after any law change
would be due to changes in enforcement and detection. For example, the act of changing an
offence from a criminal offence to a civil infraction would not change the behaviour of individuals
(i.e. the likelihood of evasion) in itself, but the related changes to collection and enforcement
would have an impact on behaviour.
3. A short summary of each of the individual studies reviewed is outlined in the table below.
Study reference
Key finding
Robinson, Paul, "Does Criminal
Law Deter? A Behavioral
Science Investigation" Faculty
Scholarship. Paper 31. (2004).
http://scholarship.law.upenn.ed
u/faculty_scholarship/31
This study concludes that changes in the formulation of the law
have no deterrent effect; rather it is other factors, such as the
method of enforcement, likelihood of conviction etc. that affects
crime rates.
Schwartz, Barry “The Effect in
Philadelphia of PA’s Increased
Penalties for Rape and
Attempted Rape”, Journal of
Criminal Law, Criminology &
Political Science 59, 509
(1968)
The study suggests that the imposition of stronger penalties had
no effect on rates of rape in 1960s Philadelphia.
Lappi-Seppala, Tapio “The Fall
of the Prison Population”,
Journal of Scandinavian
Studies in Criminology and
Crime Prevention 27 (2000)
This study concludes that a raft of decriminalisation in Finland in
the 1950s, designed to reduce the prison population, had no
effect on crime rates.
Ross, H. Lawrence “Law,
Science, and Accidents”,
Journey of Legal Studies 1
(1973)
This study, based on the strengthening of penalties for drink-
driving, suggests that the reason for the drop in crime rates was
not the change to the penalty but the increased police presence
on roads. This effect was also observed in another study by
Ross, of French driving laws in 1978.
332
Please note this was not a systematic review, so it is possible that some relevant evidence was not
identified.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
108
Andenaes, Johannes “The
Scandinavian Experience” in
Laurence, Michael D., Snortum,
John R., and Zimring, Franklin
E. (eds), Social Control of the
Drinking Driver (1988) 43.
This study notes that drink-driving rates in Finland fell after a
decriminalisation of the offence, thanks to an increase in
detection efforts. In other words, reducing the penalty did not
increase crime rates because more effort was made to prevent
the crime in the first place.
Hood, Roger “Capital
Punishment” Pp. 739-776 in
The Handbook of Crime and
Punishment, ed. by Michael
Tonry. New York: Oxford
University Press
The author finds no econometric evidence that capital
punishment has a deterrent effect on crime.
Steven D Levitt “Why do
Increased Arrest Rates Appear
to Reduce Crime: Deterrence,
Incapacitation, or Measurement
Error?” 36 Economic Inquiry
353 (1998)
Levitt finds that arrest rates have a discernible effect on
deterrence. He also criticises the methodology of a number of
studies that do find a relationship between law formulation and
deterrence.
von Hirsch, Andreas, Bottoms,
Anthony E., Burney, Elizabeth
and, Wikstrom. P.O. (1999)
Criminal Deterrence and
Sentencing Severity The
Institute of Criminology at the
University of Cambridge
The studies reviewed in this paper do not provide a basis for
inferring that increasing the severity of sentences generally is
capable of enhancing deterrent effects. In addition, in reviewing
macro-level studies that examine offence rates of a specific
population, the researchers find that an increased likelihood
(certainty) of apprehension and punishment is associated with
declining crime rates.
Cameron, Samuel. “The
Economics of Crime
Deterrence: A Survey of Theory
and Evidence.” Kyklos, 41(2),
301-23, 1988
This paper examines why the empirical evidence had (then)
been unable to confirm the hypothesised link between certainty
and severity of punishment, and crime rates, suggesting that
other areas of research could provide the supporting evidence.
Witte, Anne. “Estimating the
Economic Model of Crime with
Individual Data.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 57-84,
February 1980.
Witte found success in this paper where others before did not
testing the economic model of crime. A significant relationship
was found in the data between punishment and crime rates.
Trumbull, William. “Estimations
of the Economic Model of Crime
using Aggregate and Individual
Level Data.” Southern
Economic Journal, 423-39,
October 1989.
This paper examines the empirical evidence and concludes that
deterrence is the most important factor in explaining the
relationship between crime and arrest rates.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
109
Behavioural research on licence fee enforcement, Harris Interactive
Given the lack of directly comparable pre-existing evidence, we deemed it important to consider a study
conducted by Harris Interactive in late 2014 which examined views and stated behaviour around licence
fee enforcement.
333
The study used a 25 minute online survey, supplemented by face-to-face hall tests
and interviews, to gather the views of 2,692 adults (aged 16-74) across the UK who require and are
responsible for paying a TV licence. This sample included many licence fee payers (‘payers’) as well
as 207 people who evaded paying their licence fee (‘evaders’) and 615 who purposely delayed paying
(‘delayers’).
The study explored:
Reasons for paying, delaying or evading paying TV licences.
Views on the most effectiveness of deterrents, particularly (for payers and delayers) which are
perceived to be the most effective for making others pay
Views on different enforcement models: criminal (the current model), civil, and a ‘hybrid’ model
(involving a civil penalty for first-time offenders and a criminal penalty for repeat offenders),
including various options within each model, using discrete choice modelling. Participants were
presented with 12 different screens, each showing a particular criminal model, a particular civil
model and a particular hybrid model whereby they had to select:
o which would be most likely to make them pay their TV licence;
o which was the fairest;
o which was the right penalty; and
o which was most likely to make other people pay their TV licence.
Unlike the pre-existing literature we had reviewed, this research suggests that the formulation of the
law relating to the enforcement of TV licence fee evasion does have a deterrent effect. This difference
may be due to the fact that this is survey research examining stated preferences and behaviour, rather
than actual observed behaviour. Alternatively it could reflect specific characteristics of licence fee
payment (as opposed to other offences) as the literature reviewed did not specifically relate to this
offence.
Key findings
A large fine or penalty in the order of £1000 (significantly higher than average fines under the
current model) emerged as the most effective deterrent against licence fee evasion.
The criminal deterrents of imprisonment, a criminal record and prosecution in the Magistrates’
Court were seen as the next most effective.
Responses to the survey indicate that evasion rates would increase if the current model was
replaced with a either a civil model or hybrid model involving a £150 fine as the initial penalty.
o Under the current criminal model, with a fine of up to £1,000 possible, 5% of the UK
population evade paying and 8.5% delay paying.
o If the model was altered to a civil penalty with a fine of £150 evasion rates would increase
to 8.9% and delaying to 11.3%.
333
As this work was commissioned by the BBC rather than Department for Culture, Media and Sport, we
undertook a number of steps to quality assure the work which are described in the next section of this annex.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
110
o If the model was altered to a hybrid model, whereby first-time offenders received a civil
penalty of a £150 fine but repeat offenders would be prosecuted and receive a fine of
up to £1,000, evasion rates would increase to 6% and delaying rates to 11%.
Table 1: Predicted changes to evasion and delayed payment rates under civil or hybrid models,
according to Harris Interactive study (2015)
Current model (fine
of up to £1000)
Civil model (penalty
of £150)
Hybrid model (£150 penalty
for first-time offenders)
Evasion rate
5% (actual)
8.9% (predicted)
6% (predicted)
Delayed payment
rate
8.5% (actual)
11.3% (predicted)
11% (predicted)
Under both a hybrid and civil model the fine amount was critical: the survey responses indicate
that if a civil penalty of over £300 was set evasion rates would not change significantly from the
current rate (5%). If, however, the civil penalty was set at below £100, evasion was predicted to
increase to around 14%.
Survey responses from across the UK indicated that the civil model was perceived to be fairer
than both the current and hybrid model, but would be less effective at making people pay.
Overall, this suggests that if the current criminal model is replaced with a civil model, the penalty should
be set at £300 or more in order for evasion rates to remain at current levels. However it should be noted
that this is significantly higher than the current average fine of £170.
334
Quality assurance
Harris Interactive’s behavioural research on licence fee enforcement was commissioned by the BBC,
so this was reviewed by analysts from the Department for Culture, Media and Sport’s (DCMS) Evidence
and Analysis Unit, to ensure that it was suitable for inclusion on the Review. In the first instance, the
research report was reviewed by a Government social researcher. Questions and points of clarification
from this review were then addressed in a meeting between Harris researchers, DCMS policy and
analytical staff and members of the BBC team, which addressed specific aspects of the fieldwork and
analysis process. Harris Interactive also submitted additional data to DCMS in order to better inform its
understanding of the key findings.
From this process, the Department for Culture, Media and Sport is confident that the research is a
robust study. In particular, we are reassured that:
The questionnaire design was informed by qualitative research which included those who pay
their TV licence fee, those who delay paying and those who evade paying.
The survey sample is large and is representative of the general population (of those who require
a TV licence).
334
Ministry of Justice consultation response.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
111
o The online survey sample was drawn from a large and established online panel which
is also renewed through offline methods to ensure it is representative of the wider UK
population.
o This was boosted by hall test interviews, in which people participated in the survey via
the same computer-based method but had been recruited offline, in order to ensure that
a sufficient sample of licence evaders and delayers were surveyed.
The discrete choice modelling technique (which was used to understand participants’ views of
the different models) is a well-established method used in social and market research.
The survey studied stated behaviour, which can diverge from observed behaviour, hence the
findings from the discrete choice modelling were calibrated to align with observed behaviour.
This used an established formula and data from the BBC evasion model which is based on a
number of verified data sources and audited by the National Audit Office.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
112
ANNEX F: SUMMARY OF CONSULTATION PROCESS AND RESPONSES RECEIVED
Consultation process
The TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review Consultation Document was published on 12 February 2015,
inviting responses to the Review during a consultation period running to 01 May. A wide range of
consultation responses were received from members of the public and organisations (see table). During
the consultation period the Review team gathered evidence internally and also held interviews and
evidence-gathering sessions with a number of key stakeholders (see Appendix 1 for summaries and
list of attendees).
After the consultation closed, all responses were analysed by the Review team based on their
relevance to the 6 options and 34 questions set out in the Consultation Document, as well as their
relevance to the wider Terms of Reference of the Review. The relevant responses
335
were taken into
account during the course of the Review, and some key findings have been incorporated into the final
report.
Consultation responses
The Review received responses from members of the public by email and post. Consultation responses
were also received from the following organisations:
BBC
Callcredit
Centre for Citizenship
Channel 4
Christians Against Poverty
Government of Guernsey (Legal Response)
Government of Jersey
Isle of Man Government
Ministry of Justice
Money Advice Trust
Producers Alliance for Cinema and Television (PACT)
Scottish Courts & Tribunals Service
TV Licence Resistance
Voice of the Listener and Viewer
Additional information was provided to the Review on request from:
335
The recent House of Commons Select Committee report ‘The Future of the BBC’ was published shortly
before this Review’s consultation opened (see Chapter 4). The report brought the public’s attention to the
debate around the BBC and the future of the licence fee. However, being far more wide-ranging than this
Review, the CMS report may have prompted a number of responses to this Review’s consultation which were
outside the scope of the Review.
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
113
BBC Trust
BBC / TV Licensing
Capita
Crown Office and Procurator Fiscal Service (Scotland)
Ministry of Justice
Her Majesty’s Courts and Tribunals Service
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
114
Annex F - Appendix 1: Interview and Evidence-Gathering Session List of Attendees.
As part of the consultation the Review conducted interviews with selected experts:
Anne Bulford, Sarah Jones, Pipa Doubtfire
BBC Executive
James Purnell & James Heath
BBC Executive
Alex Towers & Nick Prettejohn
BBC Trust
Andrew Bridgen MP
Member of Parliament
John Whittingdale MP
Member of Parliament, (then) Chair of
Culture Media & Sport Select Committee
Lord Grade
House of Lords
Four evidence-gathering sessions were also held with the following attendees:
Academics and Consumer Organisations
Patrick Barwise
London Business School
Claire Milne
Consumer Forum for Communications
Richard Collins
City University
Colin Browne
Voice of the Listener and Viewer
Toni Charlton
Voice of the Listener and Viewer
Keith Wilkinson
Digital TV Group (DTG)
Sarah Clarke
Magistrates' Association (Adult Court Committee)
Dia Chakravarty
Political Director, TaxPayers' Alliance
Ministry of Justice and HMCTS
Ben Wood
Head of Crime (Summary Justice), HMCTS
Glenn Palmer
Criminal and Civil Law Policy, Ministry of Justice
Jenny Spowart
Courts Performance, HMCTS
Greg Watkins
Head of Civil Business Improvement, HMCTS
Grant Morris
Head of Criminal Enforcement, HMCTS
Anne Marie Goddard
Team Leader, Enforcement Reform, Ministry of Justice
TV Licence Fee Enforcement Review
115
Keir Hopley
Deputy Director, Civil and Criminal Law Policy, Ministry of
Justice
Maia Fallon
Jurisdictional and Operational Support Officer, HMCTS
Devolved Administrations & Crown Dependencies
Carmel McLaughlin
Director, Communications Commission, Isle of Man
Government
Paul Miele
Procurator Fiscal Depute, Policy Division, Scottish
Government
Peter Willman
Head of Broadcasting and Media Policy, Scottish
Government
Stephanie Peat
Telecommunications Policy Advisor, States of Jersey
Government
Steven Pallot
Law Officers’ Department, States of Jersey Government
BBC Trust & BBC Executive
Paul Wignall
Head of Commercial Management, TV Licensing
Pipa Doubtfire
Head of Revenue Management, TV Licensing
Richard Houston
Senior Policy Adviser, BBC
Jo Smart
Legal Adviser, TV Licensing
James Heath
Director of Policy, BBC
Ron Hand
Field Operations Lead, TV Licensing
Jason Jones
Head of Legal, TV Licensing (Capita)
Paul Edwards
Court Presenter, Capita
Gareth Tuck
Chief Financial Adviser, BBC Trust Unit
Colin Jones
Director of Field Operations, Capita